i
Published by
Husson University
Bangor, Maine
For the
NORTH ATLANTIC REGIONAL BUSINESS LAW
ASSOCIATION
EDITORS-IN-CHIEF
William B. Read
Husson University
Marie E. Hansen
Husson University
BOARD OF EDITORS
Michelle D. Bazin
University of Massachusetts-Lowell
Robert C. Bird
University of Connecticut
Elizabeth A. Brown
Bentley University
Margaret T. Campbell
Husson University
Gerald R. Ferrera
Bentley University
Stephanie M. Greene
Boston College
William E. Greenspan
University of Bridgeport
Anne-Marie G. Hakstian
Salem State University
Stephen D. Lichtenstein
Bentley University
Carter H. Manny
University of Southern Maine
Christine N. O’Brien
Boston College
Lucille M. Ponte
Florida Coastal School of Law
Patricia Q. Robertson
Arkansas State University
David Silverstein
Suffolk University
David P. Twomey
Boston College
Thomas L. Wesner
Boston College
ii
GUIDELINES FOR 2018
Papers presented at the 2018 Annual Meeting and Conference will be considered for
publication in the Business Law Review. In order to permit blind peer refereeing of
manuscripts for the 2018 Business Law Review, papers must not identify the author or the
author’s institutional affiliation. A separate cover page should contain the title, the author's
name, affiliation, and address. If you are presenting a paper and would like to have it
considered for publication, you must submit one clean copy by email no later than April 6,
2018 to:
William B. Read
Husson University
1 College Circle
Bangor, Maine 04401
readw@husson.edu
The Board of Editors of the Business Law Review will judge each paper on its scholarly
contribution, research quality, topic interest (related to business law or the legal
environment), writing quality, and readiness for publication. Please note that, although you
are welcome to present papers relating to teaching business law, those papers will not be
eligible for publication in the Business Law Review. This subject matter should be
submitted to the Journal of Legal Studies Education. Also note that the Board of Editors
will consider only one paper per person, including co-authored papers. Only papers
presented at the Annual Meeting will be considered for publication.
FORMAT
1. Papers should be no more than 20 single-spaced pages, including footnotes. For fonts,
use 12 point, Times New Roman.
2. Skip lines between paragraphs and between section titles and paragraphs. Indent
paragraphs 5 spaces. Right-hand justification is desirable, but not necessary.
3. Margins: left—1-1/2 inches, right, top, bottom (except first page)—1 inch.
4. Upon acceptance, the first page must have the following format:
a. The title should be centered, in CAPITAL LETTERS, on line 10.
b. Following the title, center the word “by” and the author’s name, followed by an
asterisk (*).
c. Space down 3 lines and begin your text.
d. Please add a solid line (18 spaces in length) beginning from the left margin,
toward the bottom of the first page, leaving enough room under the line to
type on the next line an asterisk, the author’s position or title and affiliation.
This information should appear as the last line on the page.
5. Headings:
FIRST LEVEL (caps, flush with left margin)
Second Level (center, italics)
Third Level: (flush with left margin, italics, followed by a colon [:])
Fourth Level: (flush with left margin, italics, followed by a colon [:], with text
immediately following).
6. Footnotes should conform to The Bluebook: A Uniform System of Citation, 20th
edition, 2015.
7. E-mail a copy of the final version of your paper in Microsoft Word to readw@husson.edu.
iii
The Business Law Review is published once each year. Its
purpose is to encourage scholarly research in Business Law and
the Legal Environment of Business. Publication is made possible
by gifts and grants from:
David Silverstein Attorney at Law
Husson University, Bangor, ME.
North Atlantic Regional Business Law Association
Cengage Learning
THANK YOU
Next Annual NARBLA Meeting
April 14, 2018
Salem State University
Salem, Massachusetts
Please contact
Professor Anne-Marie Hakstian
Salem State University
Salem, MA 01970
(978) 542-6823
iv
PUBLICATION LOCATIONS
The Business Law Review is the official publication of the
North Atlantic Regional Business Law Association (NARBLA)-
www.narbla.org.
The Journal is listed in Cabell’s (Management) Directory.
The Business Law Review has entered into an electronic
licensing relationship with EBSCO Publishing, the world’s most
prolific aggregator of full text journals, magazines and other
sources. The full text of the Business Law Review can be found on
EBSCO Publishing’s databases.
The full text of the Business Law Review can also be found at
www.husson.edu/businesslawreview
v
DEDICATION
In gratitude for his exemplary and longstanding service as Editor-
in-Chief of the Business Law Review, the Board of Editors and the
members of the North Atlantic Regional Business Law Association
are so very pleased to dedicate this 50
th
Anniversary Edition of the
journal to:
William B. Read, Husson University, Bangor, Maine.
HISTORY OF THE BUSINESS LAW REVIEW
In Fall 1968, the first edition of the Business Law Review was
published by then Husson College. The dedication by President
Chelsey H. Husson Sr. read as follows:
The law, written and unwritten, guides men in all pursuits
and protects their efforts. Knotty problems can be solved
only when knowledge of the law is comprehensive. To
improve this comprehension, to expand man’s knowledge of
the statutes, to aid in this interpretation, are the purposes that
caused this journal to be published. It is a contribution of
merit to this discipline and possesses value not only to the
vi
student of law, but to the layman who will find much to
interest him since it governs his every movement.
The Business Law Review continues to be published yearly by
Husson University for the North Atlantic Regional Business Law
Association (NARBLA). Its purpose is to encourage scholarly
research in Business Law and the Legal Environment of Business.
The Board of Editors for the journal includes professors and
experienced legal practitioners from Arkansas, Connecticut, Florida,
Rhode Island, Maine, and Massachusetts.
vii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
A Glass Half Full? Enduring Small Business Frustrations Under
the Consumer Review Fairness Act of 2016
Lucille M. Ponte ................................................................................... 1
Public Toes in Private Sand: Public Prescriptive Easements and How
the Presumption of Permission Supports Tourism and Recreation on
Maine Beaches
Margaret T. Campbell ....................................................................... 21
Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User
Chantalle R. Forgues ......................................................................... 41
Stick ‘Em Up This Is a Breach: A Case for Punitive Damages for
Contract Holdups
Scott Thomas, David Missirian and Mystica Alexander ................. 67
The Developing Law of Employee Non-Competition Agreements:
Correcting Abuses; Making Adjustments to Enhance Economic
Growth
David P. Twomey ............................................................................... 87
Copyright 2017 North Atlantic Regional Business Law Association
A GLASS HALF FULL? ENDURING SMALL BUSINESS
FRUSTRATIONS UNDER THE CONSUMER REVIEW
FAIRNESS ACT OF 2016
by Lucille M. Ponte
*
With the rise of social media, brand communications have become
more interactive with an ever-growing number of crowdsourced review
sites.
1
Businesses quickly learned that generating positive consumer
ratings and reviews often translated into enhanced brand reputation
and increased revenues.
2
In light of these incentives, some companies
bought glowing reviews from pay-to-post blog farms or secretly
compensated legitimate bloggers in hopes of receiving positive ratings.
3
*
Associate Professor of Law Florida Coastal School of Law.
1
Approximately 89 percent of consumers believe that online reviews are trustworthy
in evaluating products and services. Game Changer: Cone Survey Finds 4-out-of-5
Consumers Reverse Purchase Decisions Based on Negative Online Reviews, Cone
Communications, Inc. (Aug. 30, 2011), http://www.conecomm.com/stuff/contentmgr/files/
0/286c351989671ae74994fec139863bb2/files/2011_cone_online_influence_trend_tracker
_release_and_fact_sheet.pdf, archived at http://perma.cc/VA8H-4GMM.
2
Paresh Dave, Small businesses struggle to manage online image, L.A. Times, Aug.
9, 2013, http://www.latimes.com/business/la-fi-tech-savvy-online-reviews-20130810-
story.html, archived at https://perma.cc/7SJQ-6WD7?type=source. Research, including
Harvard Business School and University of California, Berkeley studies, indicate that
ratings, positive and negative, can directly and substantially impact business revenues.
Dave, supra. The Harvard study found that even a scant one-star rise in Yelp ratings
corresponded to a five to nine percent increase in revenues for local restaurants. Id.
Alternatively, a single negative online review may result in a twenty-five percent or more
decline in revenues. Id.
3
Sonia K. Katyal, Stealth Marketing and Antibranding: The Love that Dare Not
Speak Its Name, 58 B
UFF. L. REV. 795, 833-34; Kendall L. Short, Note: Buy My Vote:
2 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
In 2009, the Federal Trade Commission’s Revised Endorsement Guides
set strict disclosure rules for those compensating reviewers and
undertook some high-profile enforcement actions to try to prevent
sponsored ads from masquerading as ordinary consumer opinions.
4
Other businesses, from wedding photographers
5
to hotels
6
to e-
commerce sites,
7
took aggressive steps to suppress negative customers
through a range of adhesive speech suppression or “gag” contracts.
8
These speech suppression agreements relied upon inappropriate
intellectual property claims, empty privacy promises, exorbitant
monetary penalties, and other vague threats to silence online
critiques.
9
Certain businesses defended these gag contracts as
necessary to protect their brand in a social media environment filled
with dishonest consumers, unprincipled competitors, and lackadaisical
review sites.
10
In 2014, California enacted the first, but flawed, “Yelp” Law aimed
at protecting the ability of consumers to freely post their opinions about
products, services, and merchant experiences.
11
On December 14,
2016, President Obama signed the Consumer Review Fairness Act of
2016 (CRFA or “Act”) into law.
12
This first-of its kind federal law voids
Online Reviews for Sale, 15 VAND. J. ENT. & TECH. L. 441, 443, 437 (Winter 2013); Robert
Sprague & Mary Ellen Wells, Regulating Online Buzz Marketing: Untangling a Web of
Deceit, 47 A
M. BUS. L.J. 415, 420-24 (2010); 2011 Emerging Issues 592, Insurance
Coverage Implications of Internet, Technology and Social Media, 7, 9 (MB Sept. 29, 2011).
4
Guides Concerning the Use of Endorsement and Testimonials in Advertising, 74
Fed. Reg. 53,124, 53,126 (Oct. 15, 2009) (to be codified at 16 C.F.R. pt. 255). See Jessica
Godell, Consumer-Generated Media and Advertising—Are They One and the Same? An
Analysis of the Amended FTC Guides Concerning the Use of Endorsements and
Testimonials in Advertising, 10 J.
MARSHALL REV. INTELLECTUAL PROP. L. 205, 207–09
(2010); Lucille M. Ponte, Protecting Brand Image or Gaming the System? Consumer 'Gag'
Contracts in an Age of Crowdsourced Ratings and Reviews 7 WM. & MARY BUS. L. REV.
59, 121 (2016).
5
Ponte, supra note 4, at 78; Eric Goldman, Fining Customers For Negative Online
Reviews Isn’t New... Or Smart, Forbes.com Tech (Aug. 8, 2014, 10:47 AM),
http://www.forbes.com/sites/ericgoldman/2014/08/07/fining-customers-for-negative-
online-reviews-isnt-new-or-smart/, archived at http://perma.cc/C5MG-DZEL.
6
Ponte, supra note 4, at 78; Christopher Elliott, New confidentiality clauses can influence
vacation rental reviews (Apr. 14, 2012), http://elliott.org/blog/new-confidentiality-clauses-can-
influence-vacation-rental-reviews/, archived at http://perma.cc/GNS9-HBCW.
7
Ponte, supra note 4, at 78; Elliott, supra note 5.
8
See generally, Ponte, supra note 4, at 71-88 (discussing wide range on speech
suppression contracts).
9
Id. at 68. See infra Part I.
10
Id. See infra Part II.
11
CAL. CIV. CODE §1670.8 (2014). See generally Ponte, supra note 4, at 115-18.
12
Consumer Review Fairness Act of 2016, Pub. L. No. 114-258, 130 Stat. 1355 (2016),
https://www.congress.gov/114/plaws/publ258/PLAW-114publ258.pdf. [hereinafter CRFA]
See also Bryan Cave, Congress Passes “Consumer Review Fairness Act of 2016” to Protect
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 3
contract provisions that seek to prohibit, restrict or penalize online
customer reviews.
13
While the CRFA provides valuable and needed
protections for online consumer expression, small businesses were still
left without new options, outside of costly litigation, to protect
themselves from fake negative reviews.
14
Even in cases where
businesses press legitimate legal claims, they can face a viral storm of
online criticism that further worsens their reputation.
15
This paper will consider the typical types of speech suppression
clauses
16
that led to the passage of California’s Yelp law.
17
The paper
will also provide an overview of the key provisions of the CRFA,
including, what communications are covered, what protections are in
place for review sites seeking to effectively police third party postings,
and the permissible public and private causes of actions under the new
law.
18
This article will address how the Act does little to aid small
businesses
19
and recommends self-help remedies, outside of litigation,
that should be available to provide assistance to small businesses
victimized by social media trolls and bogus negative reviews.
20
I. THE NATURE OF GAG CLAUSES IN CONSUMER
CONTRACTS
The increasing importance of social media and crowd-sourced review
sites drastically changed the business marketing landscape, moving
away from the one-way presentation of sponsored advertising to an
interactive dialogue between merchants and consumers. Some
businesses adapted quickly to this dramatic disruption by collecting
and responding to consumer concerns as a direct method for improving
customer satisfaction and building business goodwill. Other
businesses, especially small businesses, seemed ill-prepared to deal
Online Reviews (Dec. 5, 2016) https://www.bryancave.com/en/thought-leadership/congress-
passes-consumer-review-fairness-act-of-2016-to-protect.html; Ashlee Kieler, Speak Freely
America: New Federal Law Outlaws Gag Clauses That Punish You For Negative Reviews,
(Dec. 14, 2016, 9:30 am EDT) https://consumerist.com/2016/12/14/consumer-review-freedom-
act/ (provides overview of legal issues and prior congressional proposals leading to final act).
The law takes effect in March 2017 with enforcement actions permitted as of January 2018.
13
CRFA, at §2(b). See H. Rep. No. 114-731 (2016). [hereinafter CRFA Report]
14
CRFA, at §2(b)(2)(B).
15
L. David Russell, Christopher C. Chiou & Zain A. Shirazi, Fake It Until You Make
it? Battling Fake Online Reviews, LAW360 (June 9, 2014, 12:17 PM),
http://www.law360.com/articles/545366/fake-it-until-you-make-it-battling-fake-online-
reviews.
16
See infra Part I.
17
See infra Part II.
18
See infra Part III.
19
See infra Part IV.
20
See infra Part V.
4 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
with the technological demands and real world impact of consumer
concerns broadcast over the Internet. This loss of control led some
businesses to use adhesive gag contracts to try to game the outcomes
of online reviews by allowing only positive evaluations and prohibiting
negative reviews from being posted online. Other businesses held
legitimate grievances about faked negative reviews written by
competitors and consumers trying to eke out unfair concessions and
viewed form gag clauses as an inexpensive way to fend off unfair
reviews.
21
Regardless of the reasons for the use of gag contracts, these
agreements were aimed at chilling all negative consumer speech online
and punishing those who dared to complain online. A variety of
methods were typically utilized in gag contracts. One approach
involved consumer contracts that relied on intellectual property claims
to forbid negative reviews and to goad crowd-source review sites to
quickly remove offending content. In some cases, these contracts
included copyright assignment clauses that stated that the consumer
was transferring all of their copyright rights to the merchant in any
online content about their experiences with that business. If a
consumer tried to post negative feedback, the business would send a
takedown notice to the website and threaten to sue the customer for
copyright infringement.
22
Similarly, these contract often asserted trademark rights in the
company’s name and logo and threatened to sue consumers who
included them in negative online postings. While fair use would
protect consumer postings of honestly-held beliefs, many consumers
received cease and desist letters and removed any negative remarks
out of fear of a trademark infringement lawsuit.
23
In addition, some
crowd-sourced review sites immediately removed negative feedback
once they received the copyright or trademark takedown notice to avoid
a costly legal battle over the posted review.
24
Another approach tried to ward off negative reviews through
confidentiality provisions in consumer contracts. These confidentiality
clauses typically require consumers to seek prior written approval of
any posting exploring their customer experience. This type of clause
21
Ponte, supra note 4, at 88-101.
22
Id. at 88-101; Ann Marie Marciarille, “How’s My Doctoring?” Patient Feedback’s
Role in Assessing Physician Quality, 14 D
EPAUL J. HEALTH CARE L. 361, 395–97 (2012).
23
Id. at 82; Genelle I. Belmas & Brian N. Larson, Clicking Away Your Speech
Rights: The Enforceability of Gagwrap Licenses, 12 C
OMM. L. & POLY 37, 39 (2007).
24
Id. at 123: Marciarille, supra note 22, at 395, 397; Center for Democracy &
Technology Complaint & Request for Investigation, Injunction and Other Relief before
the Federal Trade Commission, In the Matter of Medical Justice Corp. 1, 15 (Nov. 9,
2011) [hereinafter CDT Complaint].
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 5
allows the businesses to approve of glowing positive reviews while
having veto power over any negative ones. In these cases, if a
consumer posts an evaluation without prior consent, the merchant can
bring suit for breach of contract.
25
In addition, certain medical providers used “mutual privacy”
contracts to impede critical patient reviews.
26
These privacy contracts
supposedly offer added privacy safeguards to patients if the patient
does not post negative feedback online.
27
Typically the claimed added
protections for the patient involve the medical professional not
disclosing or selling personal information to third parties for
marketing purposes.
28
What some patients may not know is that
medical professionals already have both legal and ethical obligations
to protect patient confidentiality.
29
In essence, these agreements
provide no added privacy benefits to patients and are only aimed at
protecting the doctor or dentists from negative critiques.
These types of agreements may also contain a liquidated damages
clause that allows the merchant to collect a specified dollar amount for
each day the unapproved posting remains online.
30
The case of Lee v.
Makhnevich
31
is an example of these various clauses at work along
with financial penalties to suppress derogatory speech about a
25
Ponte, supra note 4, at 78; CDT Complaint, supra note 24, at 6-7.
26
Marciarille, supra note 22, at 362-63; Ponte, supra note 4, at 82-83; CDT Complaint,
supra note 24, at 3-8.
27
Marciarille, supra note 22, at 362-63; Ponte, supra note 4, at 80-86; CDT Complaint,
supra note 24, at 3-8.
28
See supra note 27.
29
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND HUMAN SERVICES, OFFICE FOR CIVIL RIGHTS
ANNUAL REPORT TO CONGRESS ON HIPAA PRIVACY RULE AND SECURITY RULE
COMPLIANCE FOR CALENDAR YEARS 2009 AND 2010 15 (2010),
http://www.hhs.gov/ocr/privacy/hipaa/enforcement/compliancerept.pdf. See 45 C.F.R. §
164.530(h) (individuals may not be required to waive their rights as a condition of
treatment, payment, health plan enrollment or benefits eligibility). See Marciarille,
supra note 22, at 391-92; Ponte, supra note 4, at 82-83; Sean D. Lee, “I Hate My Doctor”:
Reputation, Defamation, and Physician-Review Websites, 23 H
EALTH MATRIX 574, 579-
80 (2013); CDT Complaint, supra note 24, at 11-13, 17.
30
Ponte, supra note 4, at 79. See Tim Cushing, Online Retailer Says If You Give It A
Negative Review It Can Fine You $3,500, TECHDIRT (Nov. 14, 2013, 8:58 AM),
http://www.techdirt.com/articles/20131113/06112425228/online-retailer-slaps-unhappy-
customers-with-3500-fee-violating-non-disparagement-clause.shtml; Can Nondisparagement
Clauses Silence Negative Online Reviews?, THE LEGAL INTELLIGENCER (June 26, 2014),
http://www.blankrome.com/index.cfm?contentID=37&itemID=3352.
31
2013 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 43760 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 27, 2013). See Complaint, Civil Action
No. 11-civ-8665 (S.D. N.Y. Nov. 29, 2011), http://www.citizen.org/documents/Lee-v-
Makhnevich-complaint.pdf [hereinafter Lee Complaint]. See also Gergana Koleva,
Dentist to the Stars Sued for Suppressing Bad Reviews Online, F
ORBES (Dec. 8, 2011,
1:10 PM) http://www.forbes.com/sites/gerganakoleva/2011/12/08/dentist-to-the-stars-
sued-for-suppressing-bad-reviews-online/; Ponte, supra note 4, at 84-86.
6 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
consumer’s experience. In that case, Lee sought emergency dental care
from Dr. Makhnevich,
32
who required patients to sign a contract with
a copyright assignment clause, a mutual privacy clause,
33
and a
liquidated damages clause to enforce the gag contract.
34
When Lee
posted critical remarks about her services online, the dentist sent him
a warning letter about breach of their contract
35
and started billing Lee
one-hundred dollars per day for infringing her claimed copyright to his
content.
36
The dentist also sent take down notices to various review
sites demanding the removal of Lee’s posts and disclosing personal
information in violation of HIPAA.
37
II. CALIFORNIA’S “YELP” LAW LEADS THE WAY
It is not surprising that the home of Silicon Valley and the
headquarters of Yelp yielded the first state statute to prohibit gag
clauses in consumer contracts, commonly nicknamed the “Yelp Law.”
38
This California law makes it illegal to provide contracts of adhesion in
which consumers must waive their rights to post an online review or
rating.
39
This provision includes both non-disparagement and
confidentiality clauses which would be voided as against public policy
in California.
40
Under this state law, businesses that offer or try to enforce such
clauses are subject to civil fines,
41
starting at $2,500 for a first violation
to $5,000 for each subsequent violation. These fines may be hiked up
to a $10,000 fine for any willful, intentional, or reckless conduct
42
and
are not the sole remedies for such aggressive contract behavior.
43
The
primary enforcers are the state Attorney General, district attorneys or
32
Lee Complaint, supra note 31, at 2.
33
Marciarille, supra note 22, at 362-63; CDT Complaint, supra note 78, at 3-8.
34
Lee Complaint, supra note 31, at 2, 8.
35
Id. at 7-8.
36
Lee, 2013 U.S. Dist. LEXIS at *5. See Lee Complaint, supra note 31, at 8; Koleva,
supra note 112.
37
Lee, 2013 U.S. Dist. LEXIS at *6. See Lee Complaint, supra note 31, at 8. Under
the terms of the CRFA, such contracts would be void from the outset. CRFA, at §2(b)(2).
See supra note 29 and accompanying text.
38
CAL. CIV. CODE § 1670.8 (2014). See Songmee L. Connolly, Don’t Disregard Cal.’s
Non-Disparagement Clause Ban, L
AW360 (OCT. 8, 2014, 10:44 AM),
http://www.law360.com/articles/585252/don-t-disregard-calif-s-non-disparagement-
clause-ban. See generally Ponte, supra note 4, at 115-18.
39
CRFA, at §1670.8(a)(1), (2)(b) (West 2014).
40
Id. at §1670.8(a), (2)(b).
41
Id. at §1670.8 (2)(c).
42
Id. at §1670.8 (2)(c–d).
43
Id. at §1670.8 (e).
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 7
city attorneys.
44
However, the law also explicitly allows consumers to
bring private causes of action.
45
The California statute recognizes the right of crowd-sourced review
sites to reject and delete postings that are not legally protected, such
as obscene and defamatory content, or compensated reviews that do
not comply with the requisite disclosure demands of the FTC’s
Endorsement Guidelines.
46
Under this statute, non-disparagement
and confidentiality clauses in consumer agreements would be illegal
and could be voided as against public policy in California.
47
In the
wake of California’s enactment of this law, numerous other states
began to formulate state statutes to deal with these adhesive consumer
gag contracts.
48
Yet this hastily-drafted law is flawed in several ways. First, that
statute broadly prohibits contracts that require consumers to
contractually waive any online statement.
49
In some instances,
consumers may not have a legal right to post anything they wish
online, such as trade secrets, proprietary information, confidential
records or fraudulent or defamatory content.
50
Secondly, this wide-
ranging statutory language could also impact the ability of websites
hosting third party reviews, like Yelp, to control otherwise lawful
online speech that violates the site’s terms of use,
51
such as abusive,
lewd, pornographic, harassing or discriminatory speech.
52
This statute
may, in part, be inconsistent with broad Section 230 immunity for
websites under the federal Communications Decency Act.
53
Subsequent judicial review will likely need to narrow this statute’s
expansive scope in line with existing state-specific contract and tort
law as well as federal laws and regulations.
54
44
Id. at §1670.8 (c).
45
Id.
46
See supra note 4.
47
CAL. CIV. CODE §1670.8(a), (2)(b).
48
See Connolly, supra note 38.
49
Id.; Ponte, supra note 4, at 117.
50
Connolly, supra note 38; Ponte, supra note 4, at 117.
51
Ponte, supra note 4, at 117-18. See Terms of Service ¶4 (B), 5(A), 6(A), Yelp, (Nov.
27, 2012), http://www.yelp.com/static?p=tos, archived at http://perma.cc/39GM-9XPY.
52
Terms of Service, supra note 51, at ¶ 6(A).
53
47 U.S.C. § 230(c)(1). The provision states that, “[n]o provider or user of an
interactive computer service shall be treated as the publisher or speaker of any
information provided by another information content provider.” Id.
54
Ponte, supra note 4, at 117.
8 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
III. KEY FEATURES OF THE CONSUMER REVIEW
FAIRNESS ACT OF 2016 (CRFA/“ACT”)
In the wake of California’s statue, two California representatives
proposed an initial federal version for safeguarding consumer free
speech in online reviews in 2014.
55
Considering the typical glacial pace
of federal legislation, Congress acted quickly to address growing
concerns about efforts adhesive speech suppression contracts. The
subsequent final version of the new Act tracks much of this earlier
proposal and provides a national approach to these adhesive
contractual concerns. The Act is relatively short, but strikes directly
at the main questionable aspects of consumer gag contracts.
A. Covered and Exempted Communications
The Act voids any adhesive contract that restricts a contracting
party from posting a “covered communication”.
56
The term broadly
protects a wide range of communications by a party who entered into
a contract of adhesion for goods and/or service. The protected
communications include any written, oral, pictorial, or other
performance assessments of goods and/or services.
57
This broad
definition captures traditional written reviews on discussion boards to
growing number of audio podcasts and videos and pictorial reviews on
such sites as YouTube and Instagram.
Despite this broad language, the Act does exempt various forms of
communications. The CRFA affirms that the covered communications
do not include speech suppression provisions in form contracts between
employers and employees or contracts with independent contractors.
58
Clearly, Congress sought to protect the duty of confidentiality that an
employer may require from employees under agency principles as well
as from independent contractors.
59
This exception does not address
other forms of protected employee speech that may be critical of an
employer, such as concerted action under the National Labor Relations
55
Consumer Review Freedom Act of 2014, H.R. 5499, 113
th
Cong. (Sept. 15, 2014),
http://swalwell.house.gov/wp-content/uploads/SWALWE_046_xml1.pdf. [hereinafter CRFA
2014] California Democratic Representatives Eric Swalwell and Brad Sherman introduced
the first version of the proposed CRFA 2014 in September of that year. See also Eric Goldman,
Congress May Crack Down On Businesses' Efforts To Ban Consumer Reviews, Forbes.com
(Sept. 24, 2014, 1:05 PM), http://www.forbes.com/sites/ericgoldman/2014/09/24/congress-may-
crack-down-on-businesses-efforts-to-ban-consumer-reviews/.
56
CRFA 2014, supra note 55.
57
The final Act is an improvement over the covered communications definition in the
initial 2014 proposal which only dealt primarily with online communications, and not
offline reviews. See CRFA 2014, supra note 55.
58
CRFA, at §2(a)(3)(B).
59
Id. at §2(b)(2)(A).
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 9
Act, or whistle-blower protections that may contravene confidentiality
duties.
60
The law also excludes contract terms that forbid the disclosure of
trade secrets, proprietary information, personnel, medical and law
enforcement records that violate individual rights of privacy, or other
unlawful content.
61
Unlike California’s Yelp law, the new federal law
explicitly prohibits abuses of copyright law to transfer intellectual
property rights in consumer postings to the merchant or service
provider.
62
In addition, adhesive terms of use on review websites often reserve
the right of the site to remove or refuse to post content under a broad
category of illegal content as well as unacceptable content under the
site’s community standards.
63
The CRFA expressly upholds the right
of review sites to monitor or control content on their sites that may be
legally unprotected, such as libelous, false, deceptive, or obscene.
64
Further, the law permits adhesive terms that prohibit content that
contains computer viruses, worms, and other damaging code.
65
Furthermore, the law also upholds a site’s right to delete or reject
postings that are legally protected, but viewed as inappropriate or in
violation of a site’s community standards of conduct, such as vulgar,
sexually explicit, harassing or inappropriate hate speech.
66
These
CRFA terms mesh well with existing website immunity for user-
generated content under Section 230 of the Communications Decency
Act.
67
While the congressional report emphasizes the importance of
protecting truthful consumer reviews,
68
nothing in the covered
communications language expressly indicates that the law only
protects honestly held beliefs about products or services the reviewer
actually used.
69
It is unclear whether or not a merchant can include a
contract provision that prohibits a consumer’s posting of false and/or
defamatory content which are not protected forms of free speech.
60
Ponte, supra note 4, at 133.
61
Id. at §2(b)(3).
62
Id. at §2(b)(1)(C).
63
Id. at §2(b)(2)(C).
64
Id. at §2(b)(2)(B),(C)(iii).
65
Id. at §2(b)(3)(E).
66
Id. at §2(b)(2)(C)(i).
67
See supra note 53.
68
CRFA Report, supra note 13, at 5, 7.
69
Id. at §2(a)(2).
10 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
B. CFRA Prohibitions under Consumer Contracts of Adhesion
The CFRA indicates that adhesive contracts that seek to impede
consumer reviews are void from the start in one of three ways. All
three provisions seek to address aggressive business contracts and
associated enforcement tactics that resulted in a host of consumer legal
actions. First, a contract that either forbids or limits consumers from
engaging in covered communications is not permitted under the
CFRA.
70
Second, any form contract that imposes a penalty or fee
against an individual for covered communications.
71
Lastly, efforts to
suppress negative reviews through copyright assignment clauses on
consumer reviews embedded in goods and services contracts is also
prohibited under the CFRA.
72
For example, the congressional report points to Palmer v.
KlearGear.com,
73
as an example that will be rooted out under the
CFRA. In that case, the plaintiff John Palmer ordered Christmas gifts
from KlearGear.com.
74
When the items were not delivered and efforts
to contact KlearGear.com went unanswered, his spouse posted a
negative review on RipoffReport.com.
75
Subsequently, KlearGear.com
billed Palmer $3,500 for breaching its nondisparagement clause.
76
Refusing to pay, KleraGear.com then reported Palmer’s refusal as an
70
Id. at §2(b)(1)(A).
71
Id. at §2(b)(1)(B).
72
Id. at §2(b)(1)(C).
73
Case No. 1: 13-cv-00175 (N.D. Utah, filed Dec. 18, 2013). See Connolly, supra note
38; Cushing, supra note 30; L
EGAL INTELLIGENCER, supra note 30.
74
Connolly, supra note 38; Cushing, supra note 30; LEGAL INTELLIGENCER, supra note
30.
75
Id.
76
Id. The KlearGear.com provision stated as follows:
Non-Disparagement Clause
In an effort to ensure fair and honest public feedback, and to prevent the
publishing of libelous content in any form, your acceptance of this sales contract
prohibits you from taking any action that negatively impacts KlearGear.com, its
reputation, products, services, management or employees.
Should you violate this clause, as determined by KlearGear.com in its sole
discretion, you will be provided a seventy-two (72) hour opportunity to retract the
content in question. If the content remains, in whole or in part, you will
immediately be billed $3,500.00 USD for legal fees and court costs until such
complete costs are determined in litigation. Should these charges remain unpaid
for 30 calendar days from the billing date, your unpaid invoice will be forwarded
to our third party collection firm and will be reported to consumer credit reporting
agencies until paid.
Cushing, supra note 30.
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 11
unpaid debt to credit reporting agencies.
77
Palmer disputed the report,
but were unable to have it removed from their credit report, hurting
his ability to obtain credit.
78
In a default judgment, a Utah district
court ultimately invalidated this clause
79
declaring that no debt was
ever owed to KlearGear.com under the liquidated damages clause,
80
awarding the plaintiff over $300,000 in compensatory and punitive
damages as well as costs and attorney fees.
81
C. Public Enforcement Actions and Penalties
The CRFA states that any violations are considered unfair methods
of competition or deceptive consumer practices under the Federal
Trade Commission Act.
82
The FTC is provided with primary
enforcement responsibilities for the CRFA.
83
Once the FTC institutes
a civil or administrative action, state attorneys general are not
permitted to bring actions while that FTC matter is pending.
84
The
CRFA does not identify specific penalty amounts, but the FTC is
permitted to determine appropriate civil penalties under its current
statutory powers.
85
The Act also calls upon the FTC to undertake
education and outreach programs on the new law within sixty (60) days
of the law’s enactment.
86
However, the CRFA is not intended to limit the existing authority
of state attorneys general to undertake investigations of potential
CFRA violators.
87
Absent a pending FTC action, state attorneys
general or authorized consumer protection official may bring CFRA
actions in the relevant federal court with advance notice to the FTC.
88
The notice includes a copy of the complaint that the state
representatives plan to file in federal court.
89
The FTC is then given
the authority to intervene and participate in any CFRA civil action
77
Connolly, supra note 38; Cushing, supra note 30; LEGAL INTELLIGENCER, supra note
30.
78
Connolly, supra note 38; Cushing, supra note 30; LEGAL INTELLIGENCER, supra note
30.
79
Case No. 1: 13-cv-00175 (N.D. Utah, filed May 5, 2014). See Connolly, supra note
38; Cushing, supra note 30; Legal Intelligencer, supra note 30.
80
Id.
81
Connolly, supra note 38; Cushing, supra note 30; Legal Intelligencer, supra note 30.
82
Id. at §2(d)(1).
83
Id. at §2(d)(2).
84
Id. at §2(e)(4).
85
Id. at §2(d)(2).
86
Id. at §2(f).
87
Id. at §2(e)(3).
88
Id. at §2(e)(1), (6).
89
Id. at §2(e)(2)(A).
12 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
brought by state officials.
90
In emergency cases, state official may act
without prior notice to the FTC, but must promptly notify the FTC of
the CFRA filing.
91
Furthermore, state officials are not prevented from
bringing actions under existing state civil and criminal laws.
92
But
considering the massive size and complexity of the consumer
blogosphere, governmental enforcement is likely to remain focused on
the most egregious examples of speech suppression in the online world.
D. Private Causes of Action
Private causes of actions under the CFRA are not allowed.
Consumers must rely on vigilant federal or state officials to file CFRA
cases on their behalf. However, individual consumers may still bring
other non-CFRA actions under relevant laws.
93
Therefore, states could
also determine whether or not to permit private actions for
nondisparagement clauses under their state contract and consumer
protection law. For example, California’s Yelp statute allows
individual consumers to bring legal actions regarding
nondisparagement clauses along with state consumer protection
officials.
94
These actions would not be disturbed under the CFRA.
95
Although businesses are prohibited from suppressing consumer
reviews, they may still bring breach of contract actions for employee
and independent contractor violations of confidentiality and
proprietary information under state laws. The CFRA does not disrupt
the enforcement of other adhesive contract terms, only excluding the
enforcement of gag provisions that contravene CFRA’s protections.
96
For fake or fraudulent reviews by consumers or competitors, the CFRA
only states that businesses retain their right to bring legal actions for
defamation (libel or slander) and other similar causes of action.
97
IV. CONTINUING CHALLENGES FOR SMALL BUSINESS
The underlying reasons for the development and use of these kinds
of gag clauses may go beyond a mere superficial desire to tamp down
negative posts. While the CFRA provides much needed protection to
consumer free speech rights, it does little to aid merchants,
particularly small business owners, from the damaging effects of
90
Id. at §2(e)(2)(B).
91
Id. at §2(e)(2)(A)(ii).
92
Id. at §2(e)(6)(B).
93
Id. at §2(g).
94
See supra note 45.
95
CFRA, at §2(g).
96
Id.
97
Id. at §2(b)(2)(B).
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 13
fraudulent or fake reviews.
98
Some businesses resorted to these
aggressive tactics for a variety of reasons that remain unaddressed
under the CFRA. There is a need to recognize a more complete picture
of the driving forces behind these types of agreements in order to
effectively deal with the unaddressed business concerns.
First, the CFRA seems to assume that all consumers wish only to
post truthful reviews of their experiences. However, this approach fails
to recognize that competitors may be masquerading as consumers or
paying individuals to post negative reviews about their commercial
rivals. In other instances, devious consumers may use the threat of bad
online reviews to ring unfair concessions out of honest merchants.
99
With about one-third of all reviews being fake,
100
it is no wonder that
small businesses consider themselves to be the victims of many
consumers and competitors on crowdsourced rating sites.
101
Second, the CFRA envisions that owners of crowd-sourced review
sites will play an active role in monitoring their sites and removing
fake or fraudulent reviews.
102
Yet it is often difficult or costly for a
business to pursue the removal of a false review from a website.
103
Some businesses think that a site’s ineffectual filtering efforts often
delete hard-earned positive reviews while failing to remove inaccurate
or defamatory postings.
104
Other merchants complain that these site
operators have failed to properly police and verify consumer discussion
postings, either through carelessness or deliberate intention.
105
While
still others suspect that review sites actively highlight disapproving
98
Ponte, supra note 4, at 89.
99
Id.
100
Kaitlin A. Dohse, Note, Fabricating Feedback: Blurring The Line Between Brand
Management and Bogus Reviews, 13 U.
ILL. J.L. TECH. & POLY 363, 385 (2013); David
Streitfeld, The Best Book Reviews Money Can Buy, N.Y.
TIMES, Aug. 26, 2012, at BU1.
101
See Andrea Chang, Tempers flare at Yelp’s town hall for small business owners in L.A.,
L.A.
TIMES (Aug. 21, 2013), http://articles.latimes.com/2013/aug/21/business/la-fi-tn-yelp-
town-hall-reviews-20130820 http://articles.latimes.com/2013/aug/21/business/la-fi-tn-yelp-
town-hall-reviews-20130820; Dave, supra note 2.
102
See supra notes 63-67.
103
Kathleen Richards, Yelp and the Business of Extortion 2.0 (Feb. 18, 2009),
http://www.eastbayexpress.com/oakland/yelp-and-the-business-of-extortion-20/Content?oid=
1176635&showFullText=true; Tuttle, supra note 17.
104
Ponte, supra note 4, at 95.
105
Id. at 96. See, e.g., Demetriades v. Yelp, 228 Cal. App. 4th 294 (2014) (unsuccessful
challenge to Yelp’s advertising claims about its filtering program under unfair
competition and false advertising action); Reit v. Yelp, 907 N.Y.S.2d 411 (N.Y. Sup. Ct.
2010) (action alleging removal of positive reviews and highlighting negative ones to
coerce businesses into advertising on Yelp).
14 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
reviews in order to leverage these bad postings to sell more remedial
advertising to impacted businesses.
106
Third, small businesses may lack the time, ability and resources to
effectively monitor social media and to be responsive to truthful online
reviews.
107
With the growing number of cellphone applications for
review sites, consumers can instantly critique a merchant experience
before a business even has a chance to become aware of or seek to
handle a customer’s concerns. The negative review is posted and
efforts to address the matter or improve the outcome may go unnoticed
by other consumers sifting through a mass of website postings. A small
business can be rapidly overwhelmed by the unrelenting daily
demands of social media and the need to comb through and address
legitimate customer concerns.
108
Unlike major corporations, a local
business or professional are unlikely to be able to afford marketing
professionals or reputation management programs to aid them against
the social media onslaught.
109
Lastly, the CFRA does little to expand options for honest merchants
trying to protect their business goodwill. The Act permits businesses
to bring defamation actions to address false customer reviews and to
protect their goodwill.
110
This perspective oversimplifies the complex
challenges of suing for claims of libel and/or slander under the tort of
defamation. Bringing a defamation action can be an expensive and
arduous process. Initially, the merchant must wrangle with the
website through the subpoena process to uncover the identity of the
offending poster. For example, in Yelp, Inc. v. Hadeed Carpet Cleaning,
a carpet cleaning service grew increasingly concerned about a series of
anonymous negative reviews on Yelp.
111
The company was unable to
match up existing customer information with the claimed service
dates. The cleaning service had to first win a legal dispute with Yelp
over subpoenaing reviewer identities which had promised anonymity
to Yelp reviewers.
112
Only after spending time and money on
unmasking its detractors was the company then able to bring a
defamation lawsuit.
106
Id. at 97-98. See, e.g., Levitt v. Yelp, 765 F.3d 1123 (9th Cir. 2014) (court rejected
alleged extortion claim based on assertions of review manipulation and efforts to sell
ameliorative advertising, but left open other possible causes of action).
107
Dave, supra note 2.
108
Dave, supra note 2; Dohse, supra note 3, at 372-73; Short, supra note 3, at 452.
109
Ponte, supra note 4, at 88-89. See Chang, supra note 101; Dave, supra note 2.
110
See Dohse, supra note 3, at 381-82; LEGAL INTELLIGENCER, supra note 30, at 10, 11.
111
Yelp, Inc. v. Hadeed Carpet Cleaning, Inc., 752 S.E.2d 554, 557 (Va. Ct. App. 2014).
112
See e.g., Doe v. Individuals, 561 F. Supp. 2d 249, 253-56 (denies motion to quash
subpoena to unmask anonymous posters as plaintiffs made our prima facie case of libel
and First Amendment rights to anonymity not absolute).
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 15
But defamation is difficult to prove and collecting any damages
awarded may be problematic, even if the merchant is successful.
113
Most small businesses do not have either the access or ability to pay
for legal assistance to tread this likely long and costly path.
114
A good
example of this legal quandary is Dietz Dev., LLC v. Perez.
115
In that
case, Dietz, a residential contractor sued a customer, Jane Perez, for
defamation claim regarding a scathing online review of the contractor’s
services and conduct.
116
Perez’s review stated that she was billed for
uncompleted services and that the contractor had trespassed on her
property. She further insinuated that the contractor had stolen jewelry
from her home.
117
Dietz responded online claiming that Perez had
actually stolen from him by refusing to pay what she owed on the
renovation project.
118
Subsequently, he filed a defamation action
against Perez for $300,000 in business losses and $750,000 in
damages.
119
After a costly and time-consuming legal battle, a jury
determined that both plaintiff and defendant had defamed each other
online. No damages were awarded to either Deitz or Perez.
120
Although defamation is an avenue for redress, its problematic outcome
makes it difficult for merchants, especially small businesses, to see this
approach as a viable option.
113
Matt Kellogg & Simon Frankel, Trends in Defamation Cases Involving Online Reviews,
LAW360 (Nov. 27, 2013, 5:55 PM), http://www.law360.com/articles/490334/trends-in-
defamation-cases-involving-online-reviews; Lee, supra note 29, at 583; Lyrissa Barnett
Lidsky, Silencing John Doe: Defamation & Discourse in Cyberspace, 49 DUKE L.J. 855, 872-
76 (2000); D
ANIEL J. SOLOVE, THE FUTURE OF REPUTATION: GOSSIP, RUMOR, AND PRIVACY ON
THE
INTERNET 118 (2007); Joanna Schorr, Note: Malicious Content On The Internet:
Narrowing Immunity under the Communications Decency Act, 87 S
T. JOHN'S L. REV. 733, 737-
38, 751-52 (2013).
114
Ponte, supra note 4, at 77. See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 558.
115
Case No. 2012-16249 (Fairfax Co., Va. Cir. Ct., filed Dec. 7, 2012).
116
Justin Jouvenal, Fairfax jury declares a draw in closely watched case over ‘Yelp’ reviews,
THE WASH. POST, Feb. 1, 2014, http://www.washingtonpost.com/local/in-closely-watched-yelp-
case-jury-finds-dual-victory/2014/01/31/2d174580-8ae5-11e3-a5bd-844629433ba3_story.html;
Justin Jouvenal, In Yelp suit, free speech on Web vs. reputations, THE WASH. POST, DEC. 4, 2012,
http://www.washingtonpost.com/local/crime/2012/12/04/1cdfa582-3978-11e2-a263-f0ebffed2f15_
story.html; Aditi Mukherji, Yelp Defamation Lawsuit Ends in a Draw, FINDLAW (Feb. 3, 2014
11:54 AM), http://blogs.findlaw.com/free_enterprise/2014/02/yelp-defamation-lawsuit-ends-in-a-
draw.html.
117
See supra note 116.
118
See supra note 116.
119
Jouvenal, supra note 116.
120
See supra note 116.
16 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
V. PROPOSING A NEW WAY FORWARD FOR VICTIMIZED
BUSINESSES
Under both the California law and the CFRA, the operators of
crowd-sourced review sites are now the primary gatekeepers for what
does and does not appear online. It makes sense to focus on self-
regulatory measures to help balance the voices of consumers with the
legitimate concerns of beleaguered businesses.
121
Mutual cooperation
will be needed to decrease competitive tensions and simmering
mistrust between businesses and crowd-sourced review websites.
122
These proposals are aimed at decreasing costly and time-consuming
lawsuits over reviews while improving the online experience for
consumers and businesses alike.
123
A. Improve Enforcement of Site’s Terms of Use
While the CFRA properly moves to protect online truthful consumer
opinions, it is vital for crowd-sourced review sites to do a better job of
policing and handling fake and false reviews by consumers and
competitors.
124
Most review sites terms of use already prohibit users
from posting bogus or defamatory reviews.
125
Based on anecdotal
business stories and the language in business legal complaints, it
appears that some sites are quite apathetic about enforcing their own
terms of use.
126
Improved enforcement of these site’s existing terms
will help alleviate some of the business concerns about illegitimate
reviews. In addition, websites can improve their own reputations with
users by rooting out false or bogus reviews that detract from the site’s
overall benefits to consumers seeking helpful information about
products and services.
There are a number of ways to approach this issue. First, a site can
seek to verify actual consumer use of the product or service before
121
Ponte, supra note 4, at 144-49. See also, Lucille M. Ponte, Mad Men Posing as
Ordinary Consumers: The Essential Role of Self-Regulation and Industry Ethics in
Decreasing Deceptive Online Consumer Ratings and Reviews, Fourth Annual Intellectual
Property Symposium, IP Rights, Ownership and Identity in Social Media, 12 J.
MARSHALL REV. OF INTELL. PROP. L. 462, 503-04 (2013).
122
Justin Malbon, Taking Fake Online Consumers Seriously, 36 J. CONSUM. POLY 139,
140, 151 (2013).
123
Ponte, supra note 4, at 144-49; Ponte, supra note 121, at 505. See Ellen P.
Goodman, Stealth Marketing and Editorial Integrity, 85 T
EX. L. REV. 83, 140-41 (2006).
124
Dohse, supra note 3, at 389–390.
125
Dohse, supra note 3, at 389.
126
Short, supra note 3, at 452–53.
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 17
allowing the post to appear online.
127
Sites like Angie’s List
128
and
Expedia
129
tout the fact that there reviews have been verified before
they are posted to provide consumers with real opinions about
consumer experiences and preventing businesses from reviewing
themselves or their competitors.
130
Alternatively, Amazon.com allows
consumers to post, but clearly identifies verified purchaser reviews on
its discussion boards for customer consideration.
131
Secondly, sites could decide to ban users who have been found to
consistently post false or defamatory materials about businesses.
132
This method is borrowed from the “three strikes” approach applied by
some sites hosting user-generated content to persistent copyright
infringers in order to avoid secondary copyright infringement liability
under the safe harbor provisions of the Digital Millennium Copyright
Act.
133
A review site could also tamp down bogus reviews through
limits on the number of reviews a consumer may post about the same
business
134
and adopt reasonable waiting periods between the initial
review and any follow-up update.
135
Lastly, review sites have the technological tools to crack down on
individual users and reputation management companies that
consistently post fake reviews either in favor of their clients or against
competitors. To uphold their own terms of service, the use of filtering
technologies can help sniff out these bad actors through various data
points, text patterns and IP addresses.
136
It is estimated that well-
designed filtering algorithms can effectively detect about ninety
percent of fake reviews.
137
Once identified, these users and companies
127
Dohse, supra note 3, at 389; Ponte, supra note 121, at 503-04; Short, supra note 3,
at 467, 470–71.
128
Angie’s List, How it works, https://www.angieslist.com/how-it-works.htm.
129
Press Release, Expedia.com, Expedia Overhauls Hotel Reviews, Consumers Can
Now Sort Verified Reviews by Shared Interest (Mar. 8, 2012),
https://viewfinder.expedia.com/ news/expedia-overhauls-hotel-reviews-consumers-can-
now-sort-verified-reviews-by-shared-interest/.
130
Dohse, supra note 3, at 389; Short, supra note 3, at 467, 470–71. See supra note
129.
131
Verified Purchase Reviews, Amazon.com, http://www.amazon.com/gp/community-
help/amazon-verified-purchase, archived at https://perma.cc/87WQ-PVU3?.
132
Ponte, supra note 4, at 142.
133
17 U.S. CODE § 512 (d) (2017). See id. at 123.
134
Dohse, supra note 3, at 389–90.
135
Dohse, supra note 3, at 379.
136
See, e.g., TripAdvisor Content Integrity Policy, https://tripadvisor.mediaroom.com/us-
content-integrity-policy; Angie’s List, How it works, https://www.angieslist.com/how-it-
works.htm. See also, CDT Complaint, supra note 53, at 8 (consistent use of same IP addresses
often leads back to same sender of bogus reviews).
137
Ott, et al, supra note 13, at 309, 316.
18 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
can have their access blocked and their postings removed. Yelp and
Edmunds.com have brought legal actions against companies engaging
in these deceptive and fraudulent activities.
138
B. Provide Litigation Alternatives to Disputed Reviews
As previously noted, litigation seldom benefits any of the
stakeholders in online review situations. This it seems logical for
review sites to provide mechanisms that enhance the accuracy of their
postings without simply giving in to business demands for removal of
reviews. Sites should adopt easy ways for businesses to flag suspicious
postings and provide appropriate staffing to review and make
appropriate determinations about inaccurate or fake reviews.
139
If a
review is inaccurate or fake, a site should not charge fees for prompt
removal of the offending evaluation.
140
Currently, a number of review
sites permit merchants to directly respond to consumer postings online
which can facilitate dialogue between the consumer and the business,
and those sites that do not offer this option should do so.
141
In addition, review sites could offer online dispute resolution options
for their users and businesses over the potential removal of negative
feedback.
142
Review sites could create their own dispute resolution
program or reach out to organizations, such as the Better Business
Bureau,
143
to administer their programs. The sites could initially
employ automated complaint programs that allow either party to
initiate an online dialogue with the other party.
144
If the parties are
unable to reach an agreement, then online mediators or arbitrators
could try to facilitate a resolution of the matter between the consumer
and the business through e-mail, teleconference, or in person if both
parties are in the same community. These dispute resolution programs
could be focused narrowly on resolving disputed reviews or branch out
to deal more broadly with the consumer-merchant problem that led to
the contested review.
138
Dave, supra note 2.
139
Russell, et al., supra note 15.
140
See Dohse, supra note 3, at 374–75; Short, supra note 3, at 470.
141
See, e.g., Chang, supra note 153; Dohse, supra note 3, at 391.
142
Ponte, supra note 121, at 505. See eBay, Can I get Feedback changed or removed?,
http://pages.ebay.com/help/feedback/questions/remove.html.
143
Better Business Bureau, Dispute Resolution Processes and Guides,
http://www.bbb.org/bbb-dispute-handling-and-resolution/dispute-resolution-rules-and-
brochures/dispute-resolution-processes-and-guides/.
144
See eBay Resolution Center, http://resolutioncenter.ebay.com/.
2017 / A Glass Half Full? / 19
C. Establish Best Practices for Review Sites
Review sites have matured to a point where it may be time for the
establishment of best practices to guide their conduct. These best
practices could address accepted norms around broad-based content
integrity standards that both protect truthful consumer expression as
well as respect the concerns of honest merchants. These best practices
could include the bases for review, rejection and removal of consumer
evaluations, approaches to handling persistent offenders of site terms
of use, appropriate uses of filtering systems, and effective options for
business dialogue with unhappy consumers. It would also be
important to address conflicts of interest issues for sites that write or
promote influential reviewers as well as sell advertising or charge for
review removal fees to those businesses being reviewed.
145
The best practices could also address better education programs for
both consumers and businesses about their content guidelines. Review
sites or their industry organizations could develop FAQs pages and/or
video tutorials about appropriate feedback rules, the bases for deleting
or removing postings, and the importance of truthful opinion speech by
both consumers and businesses participating on review sites.
146
CONCLUSION
The CFRA has provided important protections to consumers offering
their opinions about products and services online. The Act voids
aggressive contracts of adhesion that seek to impinge upon consumer
speech through improper intellectual property claims, excessive
liquidated damages clauses, and other privacy and financial
contractual risks meant to stifle negative reviews. However, aside
from not blocking defamation actions, the Act did not help businesses
bedeviled by unfair consumer and competitor reviews. The Act did not
fully address the underlying concerns that led some businesses to take
these drastic steps.
At this point in time, it makes sense that review sites step up and
try to help support a more equitable balance between consumers and
businesses. It benefits all of the stakeholders for review sites to
improve the accuracy and integrity of their review content complaints
and to reduce the number of bogus or false online reviews. Sites can
ameliorate the impact on businesses from faked reviews by better
enforcing their own terms of use, providing dispute resolution options
for contested reviews, and establishing sensible best practices to guide
their industry.
145
Chang, supra note 153; Ponte, supra note 4, at 145-46. See supra notes 121-26.
146
See Dohse, supra note 3, at 389–90.
20 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
PUBLIC TOES IN PRIVATE SAND: PUBLIC
PRESCRIPTIVE EASEMENTS AND HOW THE
PRESUMPTION OF PERMISSION SUPPORTS
TOURISM AND RECREATION ON MAINE BEACHES
by Margaret T. Campbell*
“A silent possession accompanied by no act which can amount to an
ouster or give notice to the cotenant that his possession is adverse,
ought not, we think to be construed into an adverse possession.” Chief
Justice John Marshall, McClung v. Ross, 18 U.S. 116, 5 L. Ed. 46
(1820).
I. INTRODUCTION
This article will explore the cases whereby the public has sought to
establish prescriptive easements to coastal beaches in Maine, and the
impact which the encouragement of tourism commerce has had on this
issue. The first part will introduce the unique historical laws
pertaining to tidal land in Maine, under which many landowners hold
title to the “low tide mark.” Thus, these landowners are in a position to
block public access to many beaches. The second part of this article will
examine the traditional presumption in Maine under which public use
of private land is considered to be permissive, thus making it difficult
for the public to establish prescriptive easements. It will then consider
recent litigation in which various groups have attempted to obtain
public prescriptive easements to beaches, concluding in 2016 with
Cedar Beach/Cedar Island Supporters, Inc. v. Gables Real Estate LLC
1
* Assistant Professor, School of Legal Studies, Husson University.
1
Cedar Beach/Cedar Island Supporters, Inc. v. Gables Real Estate LLC (Cedar
Beach), 2016 ME 114, 145 A.3d 1024.
22 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
decided by the Maine Supreme Judicial Court. There the court
affirmed the efficacy of the traditional presumption of prescriptive use
when the public accesses private land for recreational uses. The
reasoning in that case recognizes the importance of access for the
enjoyment of these lands by the general public, as well as those
attracted by Maine’s tourism industry.
II. HISTORICAL TITLE TO TIDAL LAND IN MAINE
A. Land Below the “High Tide Mark”
In many states, coastal parcels are described as being bounded by
the “high tide mark”
2
and with respect to those states, the United
States Supreme Court has “established thus far that the private title
of littoral landowners remains subject to the public trust beneath the
ordinary high water mark.”
3
As a result of its unique history as part of
the Massachusetts Colony, the coastal land in Maine has a different
history.
4
However, while Massachusetts was still a colony, littoral (or upland
property owners) were granted title to the “low tide mark” pursuant to
the Colonial Ordinance of 1641:
Every Inhabitant that is an howse holder shall have free fishing and
fowling in any great ponds and Bayes, Coves and Rivers, so farre as
the sea ebbes and flowes within the presincts of the towne where they
dwell, unlesse the free men of the same Towne or the Generall Court
have otherwise appropriated them, provided that this shall not be
extended to give leave to any man to come upon others proprietie
without there (sic) leave.
5
The rationale for this ordinance was to provide “private ownership
of intertidal lands to promote commerce by encouraging the
construction of wharves at private expense.”
6
This purpose was further
described by the Massachusetts Supreme Judicial Court:
When our ancestors emigrated to this country, their first settlements
were on harbors or arms of the sea; and commerce was among the
earliest objects of their attention. For the purposes of commerce,
wharves erected below high water mark were necessary. But the
2
“The soils under tidewaters within the original states were reserved to them
respectively, and the states since admitted to the Union have the same sovereignty and
jurisdiction in relation to such lands within their borders as the original states
possessed.” (citations omitted). Borax Consol. v. City of Los Angeles, 296 U.S. 10, 15, 56
S. Ct. 23, 26, 80 L. Ed. 9 (1935).
3
Glass v. Goeckel, 703 N.W. 2d 58, 73 (Mich. 2005).
4
Margaret T. Campbell, The Business of Beaches: Public Access to Beaches on Private
Coastal Property, 48 B
US. L. REV. 11 (Spring 2015).
5
Massachusetts Body of Liberties § 16 (December 10, 1641).
6
McGarvey v. Whittredge, 2011 ME 97, ¶ 27, 28 A.3d 620, 629.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 23
colony was not able to build them at the public expense. To induce
persons to erect them, the common law of England was altered by an
ordinance, providing that the proprietor of land adjoining on the sea
or salt water, shall hold to low water mark, where the tide does not
ebb more than one hundred rods, but not more where the tide ebbs to
a greater distance.
7
Massachusetts Courts have consistently upheld this grant, and have
ruled that “The Massachusetts Colony Charter conveyed to the
grantees all public and private rights in the seashore between high and
low water mark.”
8
After Maine became a separate state, its courts
continued to recognize that “The colonial ordinance of 1641, extending
the title of riparian proprietors to low-water mark, though originally
limited to the Plymouth colony, is part of the common law of Maine;
and is applicable wherever the tide ebbs and flows, though it be fresh
water, thrown back by the influx of the sea.”
9
Recently, the Maine Supreme Judicial Court summarized the
historical title to intertidal lands:
The historical development of the fee simple private ownership of
intertidal lands has been much discussed in our jurisprudence. Key to
private ownership of intertidal lands in Maine and Massachusetts was
the enactment of the Massachusetts Bay Colony's Colonial Ordinance
of 1641–47. Specifically, the upland owner's property right in the
intertidal zone was articulated in the Colonial Ordinance of 1647. See
The Book of the General Lauus and Libertyes Concerning the
Inhabitants of the Massachusetts (1648), reprinted in The Laws and
Liberties of Massachusetts 35 (1929) (“[T]he Proprietor of the land
adjoyning shall have proprietie to the low water mark where the Sea
doth not ebb above a hundred rods, and not more wheresoever it ebbs
farther.”).
10
In Maine, the rights of the public are dependent upon “which of the
three zones of property that lead into the ocean is being used—the
submerged land below the mean low-water mark; the wet sand of the
intertidal zone, which is the shore and flats between the mean high-
and low-water marks, but not exceeding 100 rods; and the dry upland
sand.”
11
It has been well established that “The State of Maine owns
the submerged land below the mean low-water mark and holds that
land in trust for public uses”
12
and that “[o]n the dry upland side, the
upland owner holds the fee title to the property above the mean high-
water mark. When oceanfront property includes dry sand, the upland
7
Storer v. Freeman, 6 Mass. 435, 438 (1810).
8
Commonwealth v. City of Roxbury, 75 Mass. 451, 451 (1857).
9
Lapish v. President, etc., of Bangor Bank, 8 Me. 85, 85 (1831).
10
McGarvey v. Whittredge, 2011 ME 97, 28 A.3d 620. (citations omitted).
11
Id. (citing Britton v. Donnell (Britton II), 2011 ME 16, ¶ 6, 12 A.3d 39, 42.).
12
Id.
24 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
owner, in Maine, owns the dry sand portion of the beach in fee.”
13
Most
litigation has focused either upon the third “wet sand” zone (or
intertidal zone) or upon dry land road access.
14
Thus, the upland property owners have title to the intertidal land
unless they have lost their title through one of the recognized methods
of conveyance: eminent domain, adverse possession or prescriptive
easement.
15
This grant of land in the intertidal zone was initially
intended to aid in commerce, and such an inducement granted to a
predecessor in title cannot be taken from a subsequent owner without
just compensation.
16
B. Property Rights as a “Bundle of Sticks”
Despite the fact that the conveyance of land was originally
evidenced by a ceremony which included the symbolic act of placing a
clump of dirt in the hand of the new owner,
17
property ownership is
more akin to holding a bundle of sticks (or rights) than it is to holding
a clump of dirt.
18
That bundle of “sticks” may include a great many
rights including possession and the right to convey; however there will
always be some rights which are held by others such as those held by
the government which allow it to place zoning and land use restrictions
on property.
19
Other limitations on property use include those “sticks,
or rights, acquired by individuals either through purchase or adverse
possession.
20
As discussed previously, title to the intertidal zone was originally
granted to the upland owners subject to the “sticks” which were
retained by the public for fishing, fowling and navigation.
21
Recent
13
Id.
14
Id.
15
Under the common law, the land of the intertidal zone belongs to the owner of the
adjacent upland property, subject to certain public rights. Bell II, 557 A.2d at 173;
Matthews v. Treat, 75 Me. 594, 598 (1884); Duncan v. Sylvester, 24 Me. 482, 486 (1844).
The ownership of the intertidal zone is “as land and not a mere easement.” Donnell, 85
Me. at 119, 26 A. at 1018. Ownership of the intertidal zone may be separated by deed
from ownership of the adjacent upland. Dunton v. Parker, 97 Me. 461, 467, 54 A. 1115,
1118 (1903). The submerged land below the low-water mark is owned by the State, which
has the authority, pursuant to 12 M.R.S. § 1862(2)(A)(6), to lease it. See Britton I, 2009
ME 60, ¶¶ 2, 10 n. 5, 974 A.2d at 305, 307.” Britton v. Donnell, 2011 ME 16, ¶ 7, 12 A.3d
39, 42.
16
McGarvey, 28 A.3
rd
at 638.
17
2 FREDERICK POLLOCK & FREDERIC WILLIAM MAITLAND, THE HISTORY OF ENGLISH
LAW, 51 - 55 (2d ed. 1898).
18
Id.
19
Id.
20
Id.
21
Supra note 5.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 25
efforts to expand upon those rights have focused on attempts to
establish public rights by adverse possession, claiming that years of
public use of the intertidal zone have resulted in the acquisition of
additional public rights.
22
Although “the law disfavors the transfer of land
by adverse possession,”
23
clear guidelines have been established for
such claims and “[t]itle by adverse possession may be established
either pursuant to the common law or statutory provisions.”
24
While a
claim of adverse possession attempts to obtain title to the land, a claim
of a prescriptive easement is an attempt to establish an easement, or
“right of use over the property of another.”
25
Similar to the analysis of a claim of adverse possession, a claim of a
prescriptive easement requires that “the party seeking to establish the
easement must prove “(1) continuous use; (2) by people who are not
separable from the public generally; (3) for at least twenty years; (4)
under a claim of right adverse to the owner”; and either “(5) with the
owner’s knowledge and acquiescence; or (6) a use so open, notorious,
visible, and uninterrupted that knowledge and acquiescence will be
presumed.”
26
This recognizes that such claims by the public are
inherently different from claims by individuals. The next section will
discuss this distinction.
III. PRESUMPTION OF PERMISSION IN PUBLIC USE OF
PRIVATE LAND
A. Maine as “Vacationland” Encouraging Tourism
The Maine tourism industry has set record numbers in recent years,
with Portland, and the southern coastal areas and Bar Harbor leading
this surge.
27
Coastal areas have always been coveted vacation
destinations, and tourism became a significant economic factor when
wealthy summer visitors began flocking to areas like Bar Harbor in the
1880s.
28
The value of coastal area resources in attracting tourists has
long been recognized, and many efforts such as the Maine Coastal
22
Bell v. Town of Wells (Bell I), 510 A.2d 509 (Me. 1986); Bell v. Town of Wells (Bell
II) 557 A.2d 168 (Me. 1989).
23
Striefel v. Charles-Keyt-Leaman P'ship, 1999 ME 111, ¶ 4, 733 A.2d 984, 988.
24
Id.
25
Stickney v. City of Saco, 2001 ME 69, ¶ 31, 770 A.2d 592.
26
Cedar Beach 145 A.3d at 1027.
27
J. Craig Anderson, Maine Summer Tourism Revenue on Track to Break all Records,
P
ORT. PRESS HER., (Oct. 10, 2016), http://www.pressherald.com/2016/10/10/maine-
summer-tourism-revenue-on-track-to-break-all-records/.
28
THE BAR HARBOR HISTORICAL SOCIETY, https://www.barharborhistorical.org/new/
wordpress/town-history/ (last visited March 25, 2017).
26 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Program have been established to coordinate their management for the
benefit of the public and encourage tourism.
29
Beach access is essential to coastal tourism, and in an effort to
ensure such access, the Public Trust in Intertidal Land Act was
enacted in 1985.
30
This Act (parts of which were later found to be
unconstitutional)
31
provided that “the intertidal lands of the State are
impressed with a public trust and that the State is responsible for
protection of the public's interest in this land.”
32
It described uses of
the land:
which uses include but are not limited to, fishing, fowling, navigation,
use as a footway between points along the shore and use for
recreational purposes. These recreational uses are among the most
important to the Maine people today who use intertidal land for
relaxation from the pressures of modern society and for enjoyment of
nature's beauty.
33
While this language is similar to that found in the original Colonial
Ordinance of 1641, it significantly adds “a footway between points
along the shore and use for recreational purposes.”
34
This legislation
was part of efforts which began in the mid 1980s to establish a public
right of access to Maine’s beaches, and culminated in several
contentious cases before the Maine Supreme Judicial Court. However,
this “establishment of a public easement that exceeds uses within the
scope of fishing, fowling, and navigation is an unconstitutional taking
of private property without just compensation, whether the easement
is created by the Legislature or the judiciary.”
35
In recognizing that the public has certain rights to “fishing, fowling
and navigation”
36
in the intertidal lands, and that expansion of this
easement to include recreation would constitute an unconstitutional
taking, it would appear that the public may be blocked from private
beaches. However, there is a tradition of presumed permission in
public access to private land in Maine, which has provided a solution
to the beach access dilemma.
29
MAINE DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE, CONSERVATION AND FORESTRY, About the
Maine Coastal Program,
http://www.maine.gov/dacf/mcp/about/index.htm (last visited
March 25, 2017).
30
ME. REV. STAT. ANN. tit. 12 § 571-573.
31
Bell II, 557 A.2d at 177-179.
32
Id.
33
Id.
34
Id.
35
Bell II, 557 A.2d 177-79, 180, See also Opinion of the Justices, 313 N.E.2d 561, 569–
71 (1974) (declaring that proposed legislation creating a footpath along privately-owned
intertidal land would constitute an unconstitutional taking).
36
Id.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 27
B. Presumption of Permissive Use of Private Land
Maine has extensive undeveloped land and natural resources such
as forests, mountains, lakes, rivers and beaches, including over 5,300
miles of shoreline.
37
The courts have long recognized that the public
has certain rights to access and use of the ocean, and as the court
recently stated “[a]s was written long ago, ‘It will not be disputed that
the sea, which has been called the ‘Great highway of the world,’ is
common to all.’”
38
In support of these rights, as well as of various
recreational uses of land, Maine has established a “presumption of
permission” when the public is using “wild and uncultivated land” for
recreational purposes.
39
The rationale for this presumption is twofold. First, it fulfills the
need for “public recreational use of private property” that is essential
to Maine’s tradition for its residents and tourism industry,
40
and,
secondly, it “in no way diminishes, the rights of the owner in his
land.”
41
This presumption of permission “serves an important societal
purpose in that it allows for greater access to Maine's renowned
natural features by permitting landowners to rely on the presumption
of permission to protect their ownership interests, rather than
encouraging them to take steps to restrict recreational use of their
lands.”
42
IV. RECENT LITIGATION IS COUNTERPRODUCTIVE
Tensions between beach owners and the public have always existed,
however, the Bell I and Bell II cases from the 1980s are generally
viewed as the starting salvo in the legal war pitting private beach front
owners against a public seeking “all access” to what they view as public
natural resources.
43
Although at first blush these litigation efforts
appear to be laudable, they have actually caused an escalation in the
animosity between beach owners and the public, with the owners
viewing these efforts as a hostile taking of property rights for which
they have paid dearly through high purchase prices and property
taxes.
44
37
MAINE DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE, supra note 19.
38
McGarvey v. Whittredge, 2011 ME 97, ¶ 12, 28 A.3d 620, 625, (citing Blundell v.
Catterall, 106 Eng. Rep. 1190, 1194 (1821) (Opinion of Best, J.)).
39
Lyons v. Baptist Sch. of Christian Training, 2002 ME 137, ¶ 36, 804 A.2d 364, 375.
40
Id.
41
Id., citing Town of Manchester v. Augusta Country Club, 477 A.2d 1124 at 1130
(Me.1984).
42
Cedar Beach 145 A.3d at 1028.
43
Bell I, 510 A.2d 509; Bell II 557 A.2d 168.
44
MAINE'S WATERFRONT REAL ESTATE NEWS, http://maineswaterfront.blogspot.com/
28 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Recent litigation to establish public prescriptive easements over
private land has become contentious, with many posturing it as being
between wealthy people “from away” whose “acquisition of oceanfront
land has eroded the access rights of working families.
45
Public
reactions to the Maine courts blocking efforts to acquire public
easements has been strong, with many expressing sadness and
outrage.
46
Many groups have been formed to support ongoing efforts
to establish public access, including “Preserve Goose Rocks
Beach”
47
and “Save Cedar Beach” Facebook pages.
48
Supporters of litigation to assert a public right of access over private
land to beaches are convinced that if courts grant such access it will be
beneficial to the public. It may be counterintuitive, but such efforts
have resulted in a reduction in public access. Since the Bell I and Bell
II litigation began in the 1980s, the public has argued that “the public
has been walking in the intertidal zone in Maine as long as anybody
can remember, and that they did so up until recently without
objection.”
49
However, it was not until this litigation started that the
landowners had any need to object. Maine law has allowed landowners
to feel secure in not objecting to public recreational use of land and “[t]o
promote and continue Maine's tradition of presumptive landowner
permission for public access for recreational uses of open fields and
woodlands, the legislature has adopted limitations on landowner
liability for injuries to the public that may occur in the course of such
recreational uses.”
50
Such long-standing legal support has encouraged
private landowners to allow access to the public, and that “beachfront
owners who objected in the past were seen as eccentrics.”
51
Increased
efforts by public groups to litigate prescriptive easements may well
increase the number of landowners who feel the need to object, even
though they may be viewed as “eccentrics.” Thus, this litigation may
have the opposite of the intended effect, with more landowners closing
their property to the public.
(last visited March 25, 2017).
45
Maine Supreme Court overturns ruling that gave public access to Bailey Island beach,
P
ORT. PRESS HER., (Jul. 19, 20160, http://www.pressherald.com/2016/07/19/maine-supreme-
judicial-court-vacates-ruling-on-bailey-island-beach-access/.
46
Id.
47
FACEBOOK, Preserve Goose Rocks Beach, https://www.facebook.com/groups/
172580274889/ (last visited March 25, 2017).
48
FACEBOOK, Save Cedar Beach – Maine, https://www.facebook.com/search/top/
?q=Save%20Cedar%20Beach%20Maine (last visited March 25, 2017).
49
Id.
50
Lyons 804 A.2d at 372, citing 14 M.R.S.A. § 159–A.
51
See supra note 19.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 29
The effects of this reduction in public access to coastal land could
have negative effects upon tourism as the “Maine Beaches region
continues to be the State’s main draw during the summer season, with
25% of overnight visitors and 39% of day visitors listing this region as
their primary destination in Maine.”
52
Tourism in Maine is a
substantial aspect of its economy, and accounting for a record $5.65
billion in 2015.
53
It is well established that “[a]ccess to the shore is
vital to all of Maine's coastal communities, whether for commercial
fishing, water-dependent businesses or for tourism and recreation.”
54
Other recreation industries also recognize the impact of litigation
that could encourage landowners to close their property to public
recreation use. Coastal landowners have received support in their
defense against public prescriptive easements from organizations
representing users of the 14,500 miles of snowmobile trails and
forests.
55
As Bob Meyers, Executive Director of the Maine Snowmobile
Association, stated, “Landowners in Maine are incredibly generous,
and we do have this great tradition of access to private land for
recreation,”
56
A. Moody Beach Cases
In the 1980s two landmark cases, Bell I and Bell II, involving
disputes to the intertidal zone at “Moody Beach” in Wells, Maine
57
were brought by landowners against the Town of Wells. In this
litigation, the landowners sought an injunction limiting the use of the
beach by the public.
58
The court recognized changes in the uses to
which the modern public puts beaches,
59
but firmly reiterated that
“[l]ong and firmly established rules of property law dictate that the
plaintiff oceanfront owners at Moody Beach hold title in fee to the
intertidal land subject to an easement, to be broadly construed,
permitting public use only for fishing, fowling, and navigation
52
MAINE OFFICE OF TOURISM, Visitor Summer Tourism Tracking Summer 2016,
https://visitmaine.com/assets/downloads/2016_Summer_Topline_Report.pdf.
53
Maine tourism spending in 2015 topped $5.65 billion, a record, PORT PRESS HER.,
(Mar. 22, 2016), http://www.pressherald.com/2016/03/22/tourism-spending-in-2015-
topped-5-6-billion/.
54
See supra note 19.
55
Kevin Miller, Maine high court ruling on land access sends out tremors, PORT.
PRESS HER., (Feb. 9, 2014), http://www.pressherald.com/2014/02/09/ruling_on_
land_access_sends_out_tremors_/.
56
Id.
57
Bell I, 510 A.2d 509; Bell II, 557 A.2d 168.
58
Id.
59
Id.
30 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
(whether for recreation or business) and any other uses reasonably
incidental or related thereto.”
60
In reaffirming that the public has only those limited rights to the
intertidal land, the court firmly stated that “[e]ver since the 1810
decision in Storer v. Freeman, as well as long before, the law on this
point has been considered as perfectly at rest; and we do not feel
ourselves at liberty to discuss it as an open question.”
61
Despite the
fact that the court indicated that the law is “perfectly at rest,”
62
substantial litigation has ensued in efforts to expand upon public
rights.
In addition to reaffirming the limited public rights to the intertidal
land, the court clarified that establishing public rights by custom and
prescription are also limited.
63
It stated that the statutory provision
allowing for acquisition of rights-of-way and easements by adverse
possession
64
also included “the acquisition of easements by ‘custom, use
or otherwise . . . merely [as] a legislative exercise in overabundant
caution.”
65
The court went on to state that “[t]here is a serious question
whether application of the local custom doctrine to conditions
prevailing in Maine near the end of the 20th century is necessarily
consistent with the desired stability and certainty of real estate
titles.”
66
Thus, the court recognized the importance of “certainty” in
real estate titles with respect to the marketability of such property.
It was allowances for language suggesting that the uses were to be
“broadly construed”
67
which encouraged subsequent litigation, and
attempted to establish some public uses beyond the historical “fishing,
fowling and navigation.”
68
The court recognized that extending the
public uses of beaches to include modern recreational uses would
“result in a much greater burden upon the fee owner.
69
The court was
reluctant to establish a public recreational easement, and stated that:
[w]e can find no principled basis for allowing bathing, sunbathing, and
walking on privately owned intertidal land, and not allowing picnics
and frisbee-throwing and the many other activities people regularly
engage in on the beach. But there is no basis in law or history for
declaring a public easement for general recreation. That would turn
60
Id. at 169.
61
Id. at 171 (emphasis in original).
62
Id.
63
Id.
64
ME. REV. STAT. tit. 14, § 812.
65
Bell II, 557 A.2d 168.
66
Id.
67
Id. at 169.
68
See supra note 5.
69
Bell II, 557 A.2d 168.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 31
the intertidal zone of Moody Beach into a public recreational area
indistinguishable from the adjacent Ogunquit Beach, which the
Village of Ogunquit acquired in its entirety by eminent domain.
70
Many articles have championed the efforts of the groups in the Bell
I and Bell II cases,
71
however, little consideration has been given to the
potential fallout of a decision allowing the public to acquire a
prescriptive easement over private property based on public usage over
a term of years. Based on Maine’s historical and statutory predilection
to encourage private owners to allow the general public to access their
property for a variety of recreational uses,
72
landowners were
encouraged to allow free access, without concern about losing their
property rights. Thus, large landowners, such as the owners of vast
timberlands as well as lake and coastal landowners, were secure in not
posting or closing their land to public use. Any eroding of this principle
would, by necessity, require these landowners to close their land to
public use, or risk losing their property rights. If a landowner has
record title
73
and has purchased property rights for full market value,
it is unconstitutional to take those property rights from them without
compensation.
74
While the Maine Supreme Judicial Court affirmed landowners’
property rights, it also ignited a firestorm between the public and
landowners, with many of the public calling for “coastal justice.”
75
Relations between landowners and the public have changed since that
decision for several reasons, including the public perception that they
lost something to which they felt entitled,
76
rising property and
taxation values,
77
as well as increases in the number of visitors to
70
Id. at 176.
71
Bell I, 510 A.2d 509; Bell II, 557 A.2d 168; see also Bill Trotter, Judge to Rule on Dispute over
Access to Gouldsboro Beach, P
ORT. PRESS HER.,(Aug. 12, 2015), Seth Koenig, Maine’s High Court
Revisits Nearly 370-year-old Question of Public Access to Private Beaches, B
ANGOR DAILY NEWS
(Apr. 9, 2014). shttp://bangordailynews.com/2015/08/12/news/hancock/judge-to-rule-on-
dispute-over-access-to-gouldsboro-beach/, http://bangordailynews.com/2014/04/09/news/
portland/maines-high-court-revisits-nearly-370-year-old-question-of-public-access-to-private-beaches/
72
“We have long recognized the rebuttable presumption that public recreational uses
are undertaken with the permission of the landowner.” Almeder v. Town of
Kennebunkport, 2014 ME 139, ¶ 29, 106 A.3d 1099, 1111–12, as corrected (Apr. 16, 2015).
73
Maine State Bar Association Standards of Title (2016), See generally Paul G.
Creatu, M
AINE SUPPLEMENT TO PRINCIPLES OF REAL ESTATE LAW 12–6 (1978).
74
U.S. CONST. amend. V.
75
Chris Chase, Maine’s high court hears arguments in beach access case in Harpswell,
PORT. PRESS HER., (Apr. 11, 2015), http://www.pressherald.com/2015/11/04/maines-
high-court-hears-arguments-in-beach-access-case-in-harpswell/.
76
Id.
77
MAINE'S WATERFRONT REAL ESTATE NEWS, supra note 44.
32 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Maine beaches.
78
Beach owners have reported an increase in the
disrespectful use of their properties such as loud parties and littering,
79
which may be the result of a combination of the public reaction to the
court’s blocking efforts to establish public access,
80
and the general
increase of beach usage.
81
While much of the historic public usage
described in litigation has been essentially by “locals,
82
increasing
numbers of those “from away”
83
are now seeking access to these private
beaches. As a result, landowners are more inclined to block public
access
84
, and the public is more inclined to force public access.
85
The
fact that rising property values have resulted in much coastal property
being purchased by non-Maine residents, and thus many of these
battles pit locals against people “from away.”
86
The court later expanded the permitted uses to include scuba
divers,
87
but most other efforts to expand the public use have met with
resistance.
88
Many of the subsequent cases have focused on efforts to
establish prescriptive easements, as opposed to expanding on the
definition of the established “fishing, fowling and navigation” rights.
89
B. Eaton v. Wells
The next major case before the Maine courts was Eaton v. Wells
90
in
which the court explored whether continuous maintenance by the town
of a beach, contrary to the wishes of the landowners, was sufficient to
establish a prescriptive easement by the town (and thus for use by the
78
MAINE OFFICE OF TOURISM supra note 52.
79
Brief of Appellants at 7, Cedar Beach/Cedar Island Supporters, Inc. et al. v. Gabels
Real Estate LLC, et al., 2015 WL 12746156 (Me.).
80
See generally supra notes 48, 49 and 55.
81
Id.
82
“’Just because a cat has her kittens in the oven don't make them biscuits’. This odd
little analogy heard throughout Vermont and Maine emphasizes the value they place on
native status. If you were born in New England, but your parents are originally from
out-of-state, you can fuhggedabout claiming to be a true New Englander. Harsh. One
might also say someone is ‘from away,’ indicating he isn't a native of Maine” Melia
Robinson, 13 Sayings Only People From New England Can Understand,
http://finance.yahoo.com/news/13-sayings-only-people-england-150500033.html.
83
“From Away adj., People who are not native Mainah's.” THE WICKED GOOD GUIDE
TO
MAINAH ENGLISH, http://webpages.charter.net/lorilady/glossary.html.
84
Cedar Beach, .185 A.3d 1024.
85
Id.
86
See generally supra notes 48, 49 and 55.
87
See supra note 6.
88
SURFRIDER FOUNDATION, Maine High Court Ruling,(Aug. 25, 2011),
http://www.surfrider.org/coastal-blog/entry/maine-high-court-ruling-scuba-diving-6-
exclusive-intertidal-zone-0
89
See generally supra notes 48, 49 and 55.
90
Eaton v. Town of Wells, 2000 ME 176, 760 A.2d 232.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 33
public).
91
In that case, the court began with an extensive discussion of
the historical title to the property and found that “the court did not err
in its interpretation of the deeds and its conclusion that they conveyed
the subject premises.”
92
The court then stated that the elements of an
adverse possession or a prescriptive easement as set forth by the court
were that “[t]he party seeking title by adverse possession must prove
by a preponderance of the evidence ‘possession for a 20–year period
that is actual, open, visible, notorious, hostile, under a claim of right,
continuous, and exclusive.’”
93
In evaluating this claim, the court found
that “[t]he claim of right must be an ‘intent to claim the land as [its]
own, and not in recognition of or subordination to [the] record title
owner.’ ”
94
While adverse use through beach maintenance was
established, the town had acknowledged the landowners’ record
interest so the town’s claim of right to the fee was negated.
95
This
reasoning follows that of most Maine cases, where it is required that
the adverse possessor must prove “use and enjoyment of the property .
. . in kind and degree as the use and enjoyment to be expected of the
average owner of such property.”
96
Thus, the adverse possessor must
show that they used the land as an owner would use that type of
property (such as the maintenance of a road), not just that they
accessed the property.
C. Lyons v. Baptist School of Christian Training
The 2002 case of Lyons v. Baptist Sch. of Christian Training
97
further established the “adversity necessary to establish a public,
prescriptive easement.”
98
In that case, neighbors had attempted to
establish a prescriptive easement based on use of a road across the
landowners woodlot, but the court found that the evidence was
insufficient to establish a prescriptive easement.
99
The court reasoned
that the evidence established that those using the lot knew that they
were using the property of another but did not feel that they were using
it “against their wishes.”
100
This was an important follow up to the
91
Id.
92
Id. at 242.
93
Id. at 243.
94
Id. citing Striefel v. Charles–Keyt–Leaman Partnership, 1999 ME 111, ¶ 14, 733
A.2d 984, 991 (quoting black's Law Dictionary 248 (6th ed.1990)).
95
Id.
96
Maine Gravel Servs., Inc. v. Haining, 1998 ME 18, ¶ 3, 704 A.2d 417, 418, citing
Howe v. Natale, 451 A.2d 1198, 1200 (Me.1982).
97
Lyons v. Baptist Sch. of Christian Training, 2002 ME 137, ¶ 1, 804 A.2d 364
98
Id. at 366.
99
Id.
100
Id. at 368.
34 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Eaton v. Town of Wells
101
case, in that it clarified that more than casual
usage was needed to divest owners of rights, and that some action, such
as that an owner would take, would be necessary to rebut the
presumption of permission.
102
D. Almeder v. Town of Kennebunkport
In the 2014 Almeder v. Town of Kennebunkport
103
case, also referred
to as the “Goose Rocks Beach case,”
104
the court again examined the
question of what actions by the town or the public were necessary to
overcome the presumption of permissive use.
105
In that case, the public
had been using the Goose Rocks Beach, both the dry sand and
intertidal zone, for recreational purposes for the requisite prescriptive
period.
106
However, one essential issue which the trial court had
ignored was that the elements of prescriptive use must be determined
on a parcel-by-parcel basis, evaluating the acts of the public on each
parcel and the respective landowners’ responses to those actions.
107
The court acknowledged “the public's access to scarce resources such
as sandy beaches in Maine is a matter of great importance and
extraordinary public interest.”
108
It also recognized that “the
Beachfront Owners have already incurred considerable expense and
expended significant effort in responding to the Town's arguments.”
109
Thus the case was remanded for further findings, to “address one of
the elements necessary for a successful prescriptive easement claim—
adversity.”
110
The court went on to explain that “[e]ssential to our
consideration of adversity in cases involving public recreational
easements is the presumption of permission. We have long recognized
the rebuttable presumption that public recreational uses are
undertaken with the permission of the landowner.”
111
Since the case was based on use of a long section of beach, which
transected several different property owners, and since the different
property owners dealt with the public’s use in different ways,
112
it was
101
Eaton 760 A.2d at 243.
102
Id.
103
Almeder v. Town of Kennebunkport, 2014 ME 139, ¶ 29, 106 A.3d 1099, as corrected
(Apr. 16, 2015).
104
Id.
105
Id.
106
Id.
107
Id.
108
Id. at 1111
109
Id.
110
Id.
111
Id.
112
Almeder 106 A.3d at 1115.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 35
impossible for the court to issue a blanket ruling on all properties.
113
It
therefore remanded the case for the trial court to make a determination
on a parcel-by-parcel basis, taking into account the actions of each
individual property owner with respect to the public use of their
land.
114
While this ruling makes legal sense as to the elements required
to establish an easement by prescription, it creates the practical
problem of potentially establishing a public easement to only portions
of the beach. Such a checkerboard beach is not what the public
envisioned and would be difficult to enforce, thus putting an onus on
both the public and the landowners.
This unsettled landscape has clearly had an effect upon both the
public and landowners, with tensions escalating
115
and both land
values and marketability of property being affected.
116
As land values
in Maine are slowly recovering from the real estate crisis of 2008,
117
adding to those difficulties by making ownership rights to coastal
land uncertain will only add to economic concerns. Also, because
Maine is dependent to such a large extent on the tourism industry,
118
making beach access by tourists uncertain will challenge that industry
and its growth. Thus, certainty is essential to the economic stability of
the Maine economy.
E. Cedar Beach Case
The Maine courts made a move toward this needed certainty in the
recent Cedar Beach Case.
119
This case saw all the elements of the
earlier cases, with locals incensed at being blocked from beaches they
had used for generations,
120
and landowners equally incensed by
disrespectful use of their land,
121
litigation expenses,
122
and
marketability issues as a result of these challenges.
123
Through the
113
Id.
114
Id.
115
See generally supra notes 48, 49 and 55.
116
MAINE OFFICE OF TOURISM, supra note 52.
117
William Hall, New index predicts ‘slow, steady’ recovery for Maine real estate, BANGOR
DAILY NEWS, (May 28, 2013), https://bangordailynews.com/2013/05/28/business/new-index-
predicts-slow-steady-recovery-for-maine-real-estate/?ref=relatedBox.
118
FUTUREMETRICS, Maine and Tourism, Maine’s Largest Industry, (July, 2013),
http://futuremetrics.info/wp-content/uploads/2013/07/Tourism-White-Paper.pdf.
119
Cedar Beach, 145 A.3d 1025.
120
See generally supra notes 48, 49 and 55.
121
Id.
122
Defendant in lawsuit over public access to private Harpswell beach makes deal to buy road
‘to keep it private’, B
ANGOR DAILY NEWS,(June 19, 2014), http://bangordailynews.com/2014/
06/19/news/midcoast/defendant-in-lawsuit-over-public-access-to-private-harpswell-beach-
makes-deal-to-buy-road-to-keep-it-private/.
123
See supra note 55.
36 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
long history of public use at Cedar Beach, landowners had welcomed
public access, with one landowner even selling ice cream to children on
the beach.
124
Partly in response to the litigation which began with the Bell I and
Bell II cases,
125
the public began to feel the need to establish a legal
right to use the beach, beyond the historical permissive use.
126
Perhaps
due to the notion of the necessity of adverse use,
127
and perhaps due to
societal changes or the increased number of people using the
beaches,
128
the public’s use became more objectionable to the owners.
129
Loud parties, littering and destruction of fences and other property
made owners reconsider allowing the public to use their land.
130
The
Cedar Beach case
131
actually focused on an attempt to obtain a
prescriptive easement over a private road to access a public beach.
132
Thus, the objectionable loud parties and littering on the beach were not
considered by the court to be relevant adverse acts
133
to establish a
prescriptive easement to the road, as those acts occurred on the
beach.
134
The record in the Cedar Beach
135
case is replete with evidence of a
long history of permissive public use, interrupted by blockages
resulting from concerns over the public acquiring prescriptive rights
over the road leading to the beach.
136
Other than concerns over littering
and vandalism, the owners of the road had no objection to the public
using the road to access the beach. However, concerns that the public
would assert rights by prescription over the road caused owners to post
the property
137
, and at various times put chains across the road and
124
Bell I, 510 A.2d 509; Bell II, 557 A.2d 168.
125
Id.
126
See generally supra notes 48, 49 and 55.
127
Cedar Beach, 145 A.2d 1025 at 1027.
128
PUBLIC SHORELINE ACCESS IN MAINE, Maine Department of Agriculture,
Conservation and Forestry, August, 2016, http://www.maine.gov/dacf/parks/docs/public-
shoreline-access-in-maine.pdf.
129
Id.
130
MAINE OFFICE OF TOURISM supra note 52.
131
Cedar Beach, 145 A.3d 1025.
132
Id.
133
“Similarly, although litter may be unpleasant to find on one's property, littering is
not the type of hostile action that shows disregard of the owner's claims entirely and use
of the land as though the claimant owned the property.” Cedar Beach, 145 A.3d at 1029.
134
Id.
135
Id.
136
Id. at 1026.
137
In Maine, “posting” property refers to posting “no trespass” signs, as opposed to the
historical “tradition of landowner acquiescence in public recreational uses of open,
unposted fields and woodlands.” See Lyons, 804 A.2d 372.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 37
erect fences.
138
In response to these actions by the landowners,
members of the public caused vandalism on the property, including one
fence being “’mowed down by a pickup truck’ driven by Scott Allen, a
member of the public” and other such acts.
139
In that case, although
the landowners originally welcomed the public, the dispute between
the landowners and the public became so acrimonious that the public
use turned destructive:
Charlie Abrahamson, the owner of the Road from 1999 to 2014
welcomed pedestrian access over his land to the beaches, including the
Small Beach which is located next to Cedar Beach and which he also
owned. He even sold ice cream to children who used the beaches.
However, public use began to become more and more objectionable.
Mr. Abrahamson cleaned up more and more litter, including diapers,
trash, and other items. He personally witnessed users urinating on
his property and began to sense a change in people's attitude toward
using the beach. After repeated warnings and confrontations, Mr.
Abrahamson had had enough and blocked the path leading from the
end of the Road to the Small Beach. People ignored that effort and
Mr. Abrahamson received numerous threats to his family and
property. As a result, Mr. Abrahamson closed the Road to public use.
In return, Mr. Abrahamson received hate mail, threatening phone
calls, and anti-Semitic slurs. In October 2012, Plaintiffs in this action
filed suit against the Abrahamsons asserting a public prescriptive
easement exists over the Road. Defendant Gables Real Estate LLC
joined the action as a party defendant on April 8, 2013.
140
Changes in the level of respect by the public in their use of private
land has led to increased litigation over access to the shore. This
litigation has drawn strong arguments from the opposing sides, both
legal and emotional, and continuing what has been termed The War for
Maine’s Shore,
141
which does not serve either side.
The court also examined the essential requirement of adversity, and
what constitutes the requisite adversity. While the court
acknowledged that loud parties, littering and acts of vandalism are
“adverse to the landowner,”
142
the actual requirement of adversity is
looking for acts that show “use of the land as a landowner would use
the land,”
143
as opposed to acts which have been defined as “criminal
acts”
144
by State law. Since a landowner’s use of his land does not
138
Id.
139
Id.
140
Supra note 79 at 8-9 (references omitted).
141
Colin Woodward, War for Maine’s shore, PORT. PRESS HER. (Dec. 2, 2012),
http://www.pressherald.com/2012/12/01/war-for-maine-shore_2012-12-02/.
142
MAINE OFFICE OF TOURISM supra note 52.
143
Maine Gravel, 704 A.2d at 418.
144
Cedar Beach, 145 A.3d at 1029.
38 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
typically include destructive criminal acts, those actions should not
constitute the requisite “treatment of land as their own”
145
to vest
property rights in the adverse user (i.e. the public). In addition to this
analysis following the purpose of the legal elements of adverse or
prescriptive use, it serves a public purpose of not encouraging (or
rewarding) criminal acts on land owned by others.
F. Alternatives for Resolving Public Access Disputes
In re-affirming the presumption of permissive use, and thus making
it difficult for the public to obtain a prescriptive easement over private
land, the court is encouraging private landowners to continue to allow
public recreational use of the thousands of acres of Maine’s natural
resources, and encouraging towns and public groups to pursue other
avenues to establish a public right to access. There are several other
ways the public can acquire a “right” to access as opposed to simply
“permission,” which both recognize that property owners have record
title to this land and that any taking of those property rights without
due process and compensation are unconstitutional.
146
Methods such as purchase of easements, negotiated licenses or a
taking through eminent domain all respect the landowners’ rights to
due process and compensation. Many prescriptive easement cases may
be resolved by these means, and such resolutions are not only more
expeditious and less expensive than litigation, they also preserve the
marketability of the properties and can encourage tourism.
Some may consider eminent domain as a viable method to establish
a public recreational easement or title to a beach, however it is most
likely the least attractive option. While the United States Supreme
Court has affirmed that the scope of permitted public purposes for
eminent domain may be extended to “economic purposes,”
147
it is
widely expected that this standard may be reexamined by the Court in
the future.
148
In addition, the eminent domain litigation process is
expensive for both towns and property owners, due to the litigation
costs, marketability issues and ultimate cost of compensation from the
town (and corresponding loss of value to the landowner).
149
145
Maine Gravel, 704 A.2d at 418.
146
Bell I, 510 A.2d 509; Bell II, 557 A.2d 168.
147
The United States Supreme Court found that a taking of private residential
property for private commercial development constituted “a “public use” within the
meaning of the Fifth Amendment to the Federal Constitution.” Kelo v. City of New
London, Conn., 545 U.S. 469, 490, 125 S. Ct. 2655, 2668, 162 L. Ed. 2d 439 (2005).
148
LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY, After “Kelo”, (April, 2010),
http://www.lincolninst.edu/publications/articles/after-kelo.
149
Id.
2017 / Public Toes in the Sand / 39
The most promising avenue for establishing public rights for access
to beaches or other land will be by voluntary negotiation of easements
or licenses. Many reasons could bring both landowners and the public
to the negotiating table, including rising property values
150
and rising
property tax burdens.
151
For current landowners, annual property taxes can be crippling,
especially if property values have risen significantly during the period
of ownership.
152
This increased tax burden is particularly of concern for
land which may have been in a family for generations, and burdensome
property taxes may force owners to sell their property.
153
In such cases,
negotiated public easements can reduce the assessed value of the
property, and thus reduce the property tax burden,
154
allowing the
family to retain their property while at the same time assuring the
public a right of access.
In addition, when property values rise exponentially, frequently
only a select number of wealthy individuals may be able to afford to
purchase the property.
155
If property is encumbered with a public
access easement, the market value of the land would be reduced thus
opening more land to purchase by those of more modest means.
156
The most recent development in the Cedar Beach case was just such
a resolution. On March 11, 2017 at the Town of Harpswell Town
Meeting, the town approved a negotiated license which allows access
over the Cedar Beach Road to the beach.
157
This license was negotiated
between the town and the landowners, and contains provisions
benefitting both.
158
The license addresses the landowners’ concerns
regarding disrespectful public use, and use by non-residents, as well as
providing for a monitoring system.
159
It addresses the concerns of the
150
MAINE REAL ESTATE NETWORK, Maine Oceanfront Real Estate,
http://www.themainerealestatenetwork.com/popular-maine-real-estate-
searches/maine-oceanfront-real-estate/(last visited March 25, 2017).
151
Id.
152
MAINE COAST HERITAGE TRUST, Property Taxes, http://www.mcht.org/land_
protection/options/property_taxes/,
(last visited March 25, 2017).
153
Id.
154
Id.
155
Id.
156
Id.
157
License Agreement approved at Town of Harpwell Town Meeting March 11, 2017
can be found at: http://www.harpswell.maine.gov/vertical/sites/%7B3F690C92-5208-
4D62-BAFB-2559293F6CAE%7D/uploads/2017_03_02_Cedar_Bch_Rd_License_Agmt_
(FINAL).pdf.
158
Id.
159
Id.
40 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
local residents by ensuring access by residents, including tourists at
the local bed and breakfast inns, and other visitors and guests.
160
V. CONCLUSION
While litigation efforts by public groups to establish prescriptive
access rights are well-intentioned, they may end up being counter-
productive and cause more landowners to block public use out of fear
of the establishment of public rights. The recent Cedar Beach case
161
is a good example of these concerns, as well as of the best solution to
this issue. While many groups supporting public prescriptive
easements over private land feel that they are championing the best
interests of the public, they may actually be setting in motion a
movement which causes landowners to restrict public recreational use.
This would have negative impacts on the enjoyment of natural
resources by both Maine residents and tourists. Negotiated easements
or licenses, such as in Cedar Beach,
162
will benefit landowners, locals,
and visitors who wish to enjoy Maine’s beautiful natural resources, as
well as the Maine tourism industry. Hopefully, members of the public,
local governments and landowners will see the value of resolving their
disputes through negotiation, rather than litigation, and the Cedar
Beach case
163
will serve as an example to all parties for the best course
of action for moving forward.
160
Id.
161
Cedar Beach 145 A.3d at 1028.
162
Id.
163
Id.
TRAPS FOR THE UNWARY COMMERCIAL DRONE
USER
by Chantalle R. Forgues*
I. INTRODUCTION
Recent changes to aviation regulations have made it realistic for any
business to use small Unmanned Aircraft Systems (sUAS), colloquially
referred to as “drones,” to benefit their operations. The commercial use
of sUAS was previously prohibited unless the user: (1) was a Federal
Aviation Administration (FAA) certificated pilot; (2) obtained from the
FAA a Certificate of Waiver or Authorization (COA) wherein the FAA
enumerated specific use limits for low-risk operation; (3) obtained a
“Section 333 determination and exemption” whereby the Secretary of
Transportation made a determination on the airworthiness of the
sUAS and granted appropriate exemptions to FAA operational or
maintenance regulations; and, (4) registered the sUAS with the FAA.
1
In response to pressure from a diversity of business and other
interests, the FAA eased its restrictions on commercial sUAS use as of
August 29, 2016. Now a business that seeks to deploy an sUAS need
only obtain a remote pilot certification with an sUAS rating, and
register the sUAS.
2
The FAA certificated pilot, COA, and Section 333
determination and exemption are no longer necessary.
* Assistant Professor of Business Law, College of Business Administration, Plymouth
State University.
1
See 49 U.S.C. § 44711 (2012); 49 U.S.C. § 44101 (1994); FAA Modernization and
Reform Act of 2012, Pub. L. No. 112-95, 126 Stat. 11 (2012) (codified as amended in
scattered sections of 49 U.S.C.).
2
See FAA Air Traffic and General Operating Rules, 14 C.F.R. § 107 (2017)
[hereinafter FAR].
42 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Now that businesses have a real opportunity to use sUAS, it is
important for them to understand the pertinent legal and aeronautical
responsibilities associated with sUAS use. The laws related to privacy,
nuisance, trespass, and other torts implicated with commercial sUAS
use are complex. The newly promulgated aviation regulations
governing sUAS also present complexities. Regrettably, the
aeronautical knowledge test for sUAS user certification lacks rigor in
certain areas, and may not adequately prepare an sUAS user for proper
and compliant use of his sUAS. As such, sUAS users must exercise
legal and aeronautical prudence.
Accordingly, this paper offers a survey of current laws, regulations,
and aeronautical issues that pose potential hazards for commercial
sUAS users. Specifically, this paper examines the laws and regulations
of which commercial sUAS users are most likely to run afoul, as well
as the potentially troubling areas of aeronautical knowledge that
commercial sUAS users are likely to encounter, and offers guidance for
avoiding the associated legal and aeronautical traps.
II. THE sUAS MARKET
Even with the previous regulatory barriers, the market for
commercial sUAS in the United States has been impressive. Industry
experts estimated that sales of commercial sUAS generated $200-$400
million in annual revenue in 2015.
3
The FAA predicted sales of
commercial sUAS to reach 600,000 units by the end of 2016.
4
Furthermore, the United States market is expected to grow to over four
billion dollars by the year 2020.
5
By that time, the FAA predicts that
the national airspace system (NAS) will need to accommodate 2.7
million commercial sUAS.
6
In fact, just in the few months from the date
the new FAA regulation took effect through November 3, 2016, the
FAA has granted more than 18,000 sUAS remote pilot certificates, and
about 23,000 airplane and helicopter pilots (hereinafter “private
3
DELOITTE TOUCHE TOHMATSU LIMITED, DRONES: HIGH PROFILE AND NICHE, at 1
(2015), https://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/global/Documents/Technology-
Media-Telecommunications/gx-tmt-pred15-drones-high-profile.pdf (last visited Jan. 30,
2017).
4
FAA, Aerospace Forecasts Fiscal Years 2016-2036 prepared by the Forecasts and
Performance Analysis Division (APO-100), Office of Aviation Policy and Plans at 31
(2016), available at https://www.faa.gov/data_research/aviation/ [hereinafter FAA
Forecast].
5
BILL CANIS, CONG. RESEARCH SERV., R44192, UNMANNED AIRCRAFT SYSTEMS
(SUAS): COMMERCIAL OUTLOOK FOR A NEW INDUSTRY, at 31 (2015).
6
FAA Forecast, supra note 4, at 31.
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 43
pilots”) have taken the FAA Safety Team online course to qualify to fly
sUAS.
7
If the data on the sUAS users who were granted a Section 333
determination and exemption prior to the change of law are predictive,
8
ninety percent of the 2.7 million commercial sUAS users expected to
operate by 2020 will be small business owners. The vast majority of
small business owners who are expected to use sUAS will report less
than one million in annual revenue and have fewer than ten
employees.
9
A significant number of these businesses will have just one
employee.
10
Based on the early data, only around half of the remote
sUAS pilots will have aviation experience.
11
As it becomes easier,
cheaper, and more beneficial for novices to use sUAS, it is foreseeable
that most commercial sUAS users will lack both the legal and aviation
knowledge necessary to avoid the regulatory and aeronautical traps
discussed herein.
Indeed, the cost of sUAS are now within the reach of small
businesses. A basic, non-toy, sUAS costs approximately $300-$500 and
includes a modest camera and a Global Positioning System (GPS).
12
The basic model can fly horizontally about fifteen kilometers per hour
(km/h), or about nine miles per hour (mph), for approximately twenty
minutes.
13
Users with a higher level of professional interest may pay
$750-$2,000 for an sUAS that will fly at fifty km/h, or thirty-one mph,
and remain airborne for up to twenty-five minutes.
14
Enterprise
models cost $10,000 or more, and can carry a load of more than three
kilograms (or about six and a half pounds) for up to an hour at even
faster speeds.
15
Almost all sUAS models have enough thrust to fly up
to several thousand feet above sea level.
16
It is reasonable to assume,
moreover, that sUAS capabilities at every level will greatly improve in
the future.
7
Jim Moore, Thousands of Drone Pilots Certified, AIRCRAFT OWNERS AND PILOTS ASSN
(Nov. 3, 2016), https://www.aopa.org/news-and-media/all-news/2016/november/03/thousands-of-
drone-pilots-certified?utm_source=ePilot&utm_medium=Content&utm_content=adv&utm_
campaign=161103epilot
8
See Geoffrey Smith, Here Comes the Latest Drone Army, FORTUNE, May 9, 2016
available at http://fortune.com/2016/05/09/here-comes-the-latest-drone-army/.
9
See id.
10
See id.
11
See supra note 8.
12
DELOITTE, supra note 3, at 1.
13
Id.
14
Id.
15
Id.
16
Henry H. Perritt, Jr. & Albert J. Plawinski, One Centimeter Over Back Yard: Where
Does Federal Preemption of State Drone Regulation Start?, 17 N.C. J.L. & T
ECH. 307,
317 (2015).
44 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
The potential uses of commercial sUAS seem limitless. Some of the
earliest adopters of sUAS technology were industries requiring
inspection of large structures. Small UAS can easily inspect wind
turbines, bridges, power lines, oil rigs, and other perilous settings.
Smaller businesses are following their lead: landlords, building
maintenance providers, pest services, and building contractors can also
easily deploy sUAS to examine structures like roofs, chimneys, ducts,
wires, attics, and trees in a safer and more efficient manner. The FAA
estimates that approximately twenty-two percent of current
commercial sUAS use is for aerial photography
17
furthering both the
marketing and the operational efforts of many businesses, such as real
estate, construction, surveying, engineering, outdoor recreation,
professional sports, music, and journalism. Insurance, agriculture,
18
and even restaurants
19
have made creative and beneficial use of sUAS.
Certainly many other businesses will use sUAS to benefit their
operations in the future.
III. LEGAL TRAPS
With millions of new commercial sUAS users, lawsuits are
inevitable. What are the likely sources of litigation? Commercial sUAS
users are most likely to encounter tort and property claims. It is
foreseeable that a commercial sUAS user may commit a trespass,
nuisance, or privacy invasion, and potentially contravene other
pertinent laws. Upon promulgating the new commercial sUAS
regulations, the FAA specifically declined to address privacy and
related tort issues, which it contends is beyond the scope of its
authority.
20
Rather, the FAA “strongly encourages all sUAS pilots to
17
FAA Forecast, supra note 4, at 33.
18
Agricultural use of sUAS involves the gathering of “detailed data on soils, crops,
nutrients, pests, moisture, and yield to increase farm productivity.” A
M. FARM BUREAU,
FACT SHEET: QUANTIFYING THE BENEFITS OF DRONES IN PRECISION AGRICULTURE (July
2015) available at http://www.measure.aero/wp-content/uploads/2015/07/AFBF-Fact-
Sheet.pdf (study done in coordination with Measure, an aerospace industry specialist
and sUAS retailer). The American Farm Bureau predicts that farmers using sUAS
technology could see a return on investment of $12 per acre for corn, $2.60 per acre for
soybeans, and $2.30 per acre for wheat. Id. sUAS are also very effective at finding lost
livestock and herding sheep. D
ELOITTE, supra note 3, at 1 (providing entertaining footage
of drones herding cows here: https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=kK9gVzSYjJM#t=21).
19
Corinne Dowling Burzichelli, Note & Comment, Delivery Drones: Will Amazon Air
See the National Airspace, 42 RUTGERS COMPUTER & TECH. L.J. 162, 163 (2016) (citing
Jeanette Settembre, TGI Fridays Launches Flying Mistletoe Drones for the Holidays,
N.Y.
DAILY NEWS (Nov. 19, 2014), http://m.nydailynews.com/life-style/eats/tgi-fridays-
launches-mistletoe-drones-article-1.2016401.
20
FAA, Fact Sheet – Small Unmanned Aircraft Regulations (Part 107), June 21, 2016,
available at https://www.faa.gov/news/fact_sheets/news_story.cfm?newsId=20516. The
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 45
check local and state laws.”
21
These existing laws are based in
traditional common law and can be complicated, particularly as they
apply to sUAS. It is important, then, for commercial sUAS users to
develop a basic understanding of applicable tort, property, and other
related laws, and to create conservative strategies to avoid legal
transgressions.
A. Trespass
How can a commercial sUAS user avoid a trespass lawsuit?
Trespass is most basically defined as the intrusion on the land of
another without privilege.
22
The easiest way to avoid a trespass claim,
therefore, is to refrain from flying over the land of another. Another
easy way to avoid a trespass lawsuit is to obtain consent to overfly the
land of another.
23
There are many occasions, however, when it is
impossible or impractical to avoid flying over the land of another
(including inadvertent overflight), or to obtain permission to do so. As
such, sUAS users should be sensitive to the disposition of the law of
trespass.
State laws on aerial trespass vary, but most are based on
fundamental common law principles. Section 159 of the Restatement
(Second) of Torts (“Restatement”), Intrusions Upon, Beneath and
Above the Surface of the Earth, provides that: “Flight by aircraft
24
in
the air space above the land of another is a trespass if, but only if, (a)
It enters into the immediate reaches of the air space next to the land,
and (b) It interferes substantially with the other’s use and enjoyment
of his land.”
25
The Restatement does not define precisely what
constitutes, “immediate reaches,” but it does provide that, “In the
ordinary case, flight at 500 feet or more above the surface is not within
the ‘immediate reaches,’ while flight within 50 feet, which interferes
FAA, however, does recommend that sUAS pilots follow the National
Telecommunications and Information Administration’s “Best Practices” for privacy,
which provides a few practical tips on how to be “neighborly,” among other advice. Id.
According to the FAA, these guidelines are not intended to set the legal standard. Id.
21
Id.
22
RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS §§ 158, 163, 164 & 165 (1965).
23
Id. at §167.
24
In the FAA Modernization and Reform Act of 2012, Congress defined an sUAS as
“an aircraft that is operated without the possibility of direct human intervention from
within or on the aircraft.” Sec. 331(8), Pub. L. 112-95 (2012). In Administrator v. Pirker,
the National Transportation Safety Board (NTSB) unanimously determined that sUAS
are “aircraft,” for the purpose of regulatory liability. NTSB Order No. EA-5730 (Nov. 17,
2014) available at http://www.ntsb.gov/legal/alj/Documents/5730.pdf. It follows that
sUAS should also be considered “aircraft,” for the purpose of tort liability.
25
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 159 (emphasis added).
46 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
with actual use, clearly is, and flight within 150 feet, which also
interferes, may present a question of fact.”
26
The concept of “immediate reaches” stems from the seminal case on
aerial trespass by aviation, United States v. Causby.
27
In Causby, the
Court explained that, “It is obvious that if the landowner is to have full
enjoyment of the land, he must have exclusive control of the immediate
reaches of the enveloping atmosphere.”
28
According to the Causby
Court, the landowner “owns at least as much of the space above the
ground as he can occupy or use in connection with the land.”
29
Conversely, it seems, the Court established that there are no private
property rights to the land beyond the “immediate reaches.” Upon
remand, the Court of Claims awarded damages to the landowners for
flights that occurred up to 365 feet, which was 300 feet above the tallest
object on the property.
30
At that time, the Civil Aeronautics Authority
31
had set 300 feet as the minimum safe altitude at which an aircraft
could fly over any sort of terrain.
32
Courts have found trespass by aircraft flying anywhere between
fifty feet
33
above ground level (AGL)
34
to 999 feet AGL over the property
of another.
35
Aircraft flying less than 100 feet AGL are frequently held
26
Id. at cmt. l.
27
328 U.S. 256 (1946). Prior to Causby, common law had long recognized the concept
of aerial trespass through means other than aviation. See, e.g., Whittaker v. Stangvick,
100 Minn. 386 (1907) (shooting over another's land); Butler v. Frontier Telephone Co. 186
N.Y. 486 (1906) (wires strung over land twenty or thirty feet above surface); Barnes v.
Berendes, 139 Cal. 32 (1903) (walls leaning over property); Ellis v. Loftus Iron Co. (1874)
L.R. 10 C.P. 10 (U.K.) (horse kicking into another’s space).
28
Causby, 328 U.S. at 264.
29
Id.
30
Causby v. U.S., 109 Ct. Cl. 768 (1948). The tallest object on the property was a sixty-
five foot tree.
31
The Civil Aeronautics Authority was the precursor agency to the FAA. FAA, A Brief
History of the FAA, (page last modified on Feb. 19, 2015) available at
https://www.faa.gov/about/history/brief_history/.
32
See Causby, 109 Ct. Cl. at 770.
33
See, e.g., Brandes v. Mitterling, 67 Ariz. 349 (1948).
34
In aviation, AGL altitude is the absolute height measured against the underlying
ground surface, and it distinguished from altitude above mean sea level (MSL), which is
the measurement of the height of an aircraft above the average sea level. J
EPPESEN,
GUIDED FLIGHT DISCOVERY: PRIVATE PILOT 2-56 & 2-58 (2007).
35
See Brandes, 67 Ariz. at 356-57 citing Mohican & Reena, Inc., v. Tobiasz, 1938
U.S.Av.Rep. 1 (master's report filed in Super.Ct. Hampden, Mass., 1938) (injunction
granted for children’s summer camp owner prohibiting flight below 1,000 feet within 500
feet of property). It should be noted that common law cases, including Brandes, often
muddle the laws of trespass and nuisance. This is particularly true in aviation cases
where courts have a history of labelling trespassory actions as nuisance claims. See
Henry E. Smith, Exclusion and Property Rules in the Law of Nuisance, 90 V
A. L. REV.
965, 984 (2004).
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 47
liable pursuant to trespass law suits,
36
although many courts have
decided that 500 feet AGL is the limit for aerial trespass.
37
The FAA’s
civil air regulations now provide that 500 feet AGL is the minimum
safe flight altitude for aircraft over non-congested areas,
38
and 1000
feet AGL is the minimum safe flight altitude over congested areas.
39
Flight at or above these limits constitutes publically “navigable
airspace”
40
and may constitute a reasonable marker for determination
of liability.
41
Notwithstanding the FAA’s declaration on minimum safe
altitudes, some courts have determined that the altitude of overflight
has no determinative impact on liability, finding that, “although the
navigable airspace has been declared to be in the public domain,
regardless of any congressional limitations, the land owner, as an
incident to his ownership, has a claim to the superjacent airspace to
the extent that a reasonable use of his land involves such space.”
42
A trespass claim, regardless of the altitude of the trespass, further
requires a substantial interference with another’s use and enjoyment
of land.
43
There must be interference with actual, as distinguished from
potential, use.
44
Notably, an otherwise nonharmful -even beneficial-
intentional intrusion, will still subject an sUAS user to liability if the
intrusion interferes with the use and enjoyment of land.
45
Courts have
been more likely to find interference when the invasion occurs over
“cultivated” land that is occupied and used, rather than land covered
in dense brush or woods.
46
Most aircraft produce offensive noise, dust,
light, vibration, and other air pollution. For these reasons, there
appears to be little difficulty for a court to find that most low-flying
36
See, e.g., Vanderslice v. Shawn, Del. Ch., 27 A.2d 87 (1942); Smith v. New England
Aircraft, 270 Mass. 511 (1930); Dlugos v. United Air Lines, 1944 U.S.Av.Rep.
(Ct.Comm.Pl.Pa. Lehigh Co., May 27, 1944).
37
See, e.g., Burnham v. Beverly Airways, Inc., 311 Mass. 628 (1942); see also
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 159 cmt. 2(l).
38
FAR, supra note 2, at § 91.119(c).
39
Id. at § 91.119(b) (such flight is unsafe within horizontal distance of 2,000 feet from
congested area).
40
FAR, supra note 2, at § 1.1.
41
See, e.g., Brenner v. New Richmond Regional Airport Com’n, 816 N.W.2 291, 306
(2012). While helicopters, powered parachutes, and weight-shift control aircraft are
permitted to operate at less than these minimum altitudes under certain circumstances,
FAR §91.119(d), this does not mean that such operation is conducted within navigable
airspace. People v. Sabo, 185 Cal. App. 3d 845, 852 (1986); nor is this always considered
best practice.
42
Palisades Citizens Ass’n, Inc. v. C.A.B, 420 F.2d 188, 192 (D.C. Cir. 1969) (internal
quotations omitted) (citing US v. 15,909 Acres, 176 F.Supp. 447, 448 (1958)).
43
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 159 (2)(b).
44
Id. at cmt. k.
45
Accord id. at § 163.
46
Smith, 270 Mass. at 531.
48 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
aircraft substantially interfere with the use and enjoyment of occupied
land. This is particularly true if the flights are frequent and occur at
times unsuitable to the landowner.
It is important to note that intrusions over land by mistake will also
subject an sUAS user to trespass liability.
47
An sUAS user who acts
under a mistaken belief of law or fact, however reasonable his belief,
will be liable to a landowner for an overflight.
48
Under the
Restatement, an sUAS user would be liable for a mistaken intrusion
over the land of another even if he acted pursuant to “the advice of the
most eminent counsel,” or pursuant to a lawful statute that was
subsequently determined unconstitutional.
49
An sUAS user, therefore,
would be liable for a good-faith but mistaken belief about a boundary
line.
50
For several reasons, the “mistaken belief” provision is
particularly perilous for sUAS users. As discussed more fully below in
this section and in section IV.D, there are many ways an sUAS user
could have a mistaken belief about his location, and therefore be liable
in trespass.
Trespass offers strong remedies for plaintiffs. Courts award a full
range of damages against trespassers, including nominal,
compensatory, consequential, and even punitive damages for
intentional conduct.
51
This can include the diminution of market value
of the land at issue, the cost of restoration of the land, the loss of use
of the land, and emotional distress damages, even when there is no
physical injury to the person or land.
52
A court may also order
injunctive relief against a trespasser for both current and future
threatened harm.
53
Accordingly, a defendant in trespass may be liable
for damages that are far beyond those normally imposed in a
negligence action.
54
Small UAS users, therefore, may be liable for flying too low and
interfering with the use and enjoyment of another’s land. Although
sUAS may not produce as much dust or vibration as the aircraft
involved in traditional aerial trespass cases, sUAS can be very
intrusive at lower altitudes. Small UAS move slower, fly nearer to
individuals, and typically remain over property for a longer period of
time than most aircraft. They can follow people closely and look in their
47
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 164.
48
Id.
49
Id. at cmt. a.
50
Id. at cmt. c.(2).
51
See 75 AM. JUR. 2D Trespass §§ 86-127 (2011).
52
See generally id.
53
See id. at §§ 86-90.
54
See id. at §§ 100 & 130.
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 49
windows. Small UAS can even record, store, and broadcast an
individual’s activities (or lack thereof). Small UAS also tend to provoke
the ire of dogs.
55
If a dog owner who permits excessive or untimely
barking is liable for interfering with another’s use and enjoyment of
land,
56
it follows that anyone who causes such barking, including by
means of sUAS, has also interfered with a landowner’s use and
enjoyment of land, and would be liable for trespass.
Overflying sUAS seem innately to incite fear and anger in many
humans. As such, its very presence may automatically disturb the use
and enjoyment of land. If flown at a low enough altitude, say, within
gunshot range, overflying sUAS would necessarily interfere with the
immediate reaches of land. Indeed, flying an sUAS at a low enough
altitude may get one’s sUAS shot down. For example, it appears that
such physical force to prevent a trespass may be justified under
Kentucky law,
57
notwithstanding the federal statute that could be
construed to the contrary.
58
One Colorado town has even considered
passing an ordinance to issue hunting licenses to shoot down sUAS and
establish a bounty system rewarding the hunters.
59
It is clear then,
that sUAS users may be readily subject to trespass liability, which can
trigger either a costly damage award, or a costly abatement.
55
Accord Perritt & Plawinski, supra note 16, at 310.
56
See, e.g., City of Belfield v. Kilkenny, 729 N.W.2d 120, 128 (2007).
57
Ky. Rev. Stat. Ann. § 503.080(1)(a) (2006) (physical force justified for protection of
property from trespass). In one Kentucky case, a man shot down an sUAS that he claimed
was observing his daughter who was sunbathing in his yard. There was disputed evidence
concerning whether the sUAS was flying below tree level, but a trial court determined that
shooting down the sUAS in response to the invasion did not constitute criminal mischief.
Elisha Fieldstadt, Case Dismissed against William H. Merideth, Kentucky Man Arrested for
Shooting Down Drone, NBC N
EWS (Oct. 27, 2015, 1:28 PM), http://www.nbcnews.com/
news/us-news/case-dismissed-against-william-h-merideth-kentucky-man-arrested-shooting-
n452281. Compare Massachusetts law, Commonwealth v. Haddock, 46 Mass. App. Ct. 246,
248 n.2 & 249 (1999) (reasonable, nondeadly force permitted to defend property from
trespass). See also Ashley Codiannia, CNN Exclusive: Snapchat Interview with Senator Rand
Paul, CNN, http://www.cnn.com/2015/01/28/politics/rand-paul-snaphat-interview/ (last
updated Jan. 28, 2015, 11:32 AM) (quoting Rand Paul: "drones should only be used according
to the Constitution. But if they fly over my house, they better be aware because I've got a
shotgun.")
58
Anyone who shoots at an “aircraft,” may be sentenced for up to twenty years in
federal prison, 18 U.S.C. § 32(a) (2016), in addition to facing a fine of up to $250,000. Id.
at 3571(b). Merely threatening to down an aircraft is punishable by up to five years in
prison and the same steep fine. Id. at §32(c) & 3571(b).
59
Ryan Grenoble, Drone Hunting in Deer Trail, Colorado? Town Considers Bounty for
Unmanned Aerial Vehicles, H
UFFINGTON POST (Jul. 17, 2013, 4:02 PM),
http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2013/07/17/drone-hunting-deer-
trailcolorado_n_3611806.html, archived at http://perma.cc/6ZE2-P4WP.
50 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
What guidance can be gleaned for sUAS users from the state of
trespass law? First, common law suggests that when flying over the
land of another, it would be prudent to fly at an altitude of at least 500
feet AGL over non-congested land and 1000 feet AGL over congested
land, which is the FAA’s minimum safe altitude for most aircraft. The
new sUAS regulations, however, restrict sUAS flight to no more than
400 feet AGL.
60
Ideally, sUAS users should fly as close to 400 feet AGL
as possible when flying over the land of another, particularly when that
land is occupied and in use. One scholar suggests a “rule of thumb” that
sUAS users fly at the treetop or powerline level,
61
but this is not ideal.
The Causby court found tort liability for aircraft flying 300 feet above
the tree level.
62
If it is necessary to fly an sUAS lower, and oftentimes
it is,
63
an sUAS user should remain higher than 150 feet AGL because
the Restatement comments that flying at 150 feet may present a
“question of fact” for liability. Small UAS users should certainly refrain
from overflying the land of another at less than 100 feet AGL, given
the case law favoring landowners at that altitude. Retailers such as
Google, who are testing delivery sUAS as low as 130 feet AGL, should
probably adjust their operations accordingly.
64
Second, sUAS users should fly in a way that avoids interfering with
another’s use and enjoyment of his land. While this seems like a
common sense standard, current newsworthy use of sUAS suggests
that common sense does not prevail.
65
It is advisable, therefore, for
sUAS users to refrain from excessive noise-making, dust-causing, and
light-generating activity, particularly over congested and cultivated
land. Operators should also avoid hovering, repeated overflying,
following, “peeping” on, and recording individuals. And, while some
sUAS users innocently, or even beneficially, engage in some of these
60
FAR, supra note 2, at §107.51(b).
61
Perritt & Plawinski, supra note 16, at 347-348.
62
See Causby, 109 Ct. Cl. at 770.
63
For example, an sUAS user may have to fly lower to avoid clouds pursuant to FAR
§ 107.51(d).
64
Alistair Barr & Greg Bensinger, Google Is Testing Delivery Drone System:
Amazon.com, Domino’s Pizza Have also Tested Delivery Drones, W
ALL ST. J. (Aug. 29,
2014, 4:04 AM), http://www.wsj.com/articles/google-reveals-delivery-drone-project-
1409274480.
65
See, e.g., Fieldstadt, supra note 57 (observing sunbathing teenager); Aaron West,
Redmond Exploring whether Drone Spying Violates Nuisance Law, W
ASH. TIMES (June 17,
2016), http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2016/jun/17/redmond-exploring-whether-
drone- spying-violates-nu/ (repeated overflying of home); Michael Rosenfield, New Hampshire
Residents Report Seeing Drones Hover Over their Skylights, N.
E. CABLE NEWS (Jan. 11, 2017),
http://www.necn.com/news/new-england/New-Hampshire-Residents-Report-Seeing-Drones-
Hovering-Over-Their-Skylights-410339885.html?_osource=taboola-recirc (hovering over
skylights in house).
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 51
activities, these users should obtain permission from the pertinent
landowner(s) to do so in order to avoid trespass and other liability.
It is also very important for sUAS users to take the time to develop
and maintain proficiency in operating sUAS. Small UAS can be
difficult to fly at first, and they do require self-training to operate.
Surprisingly, the testing required to obtain an sUAS remote pilot
certificate does not require practical training or aeronautical
experience. Small UAS users, therefore, are responsible for their own
flight proficiency. There is a similar learning curve with respect to
understanding sUAS software applications,
66
and how to undertake
contemporaneous physical and software operations in-flight. Lack of
proficiency could cause a trespass, subjecting an sUAS user to tort
liability.
It is equally important for sUAS users to study the operating
limitations of their particular sUAS. Small UAS users must
understand the performance capabilities of their particular sUAS,
including specific speed and maneuverability limitations; function and
capacity limitations with respect to weight, load, and balance issues;
overall visual limitations; weather limitations, likely operational
failures;
67
and performance limitations inherent to all possible weather
scenarios. Failure to adjust to differing operating circumstances could
cause the sUAS to intrude into the immediate reaches of another’s air
space and interfere with the use and enjoyment of land, thereby
triggering trespass liability.
There are, moreover, many circumstances under which an sUAS
user could misapprehend his location,
68
making it more likely he would
cause a trespass. For example, a commercial sUAS user may not
understand topography, navigation, weather conditions, mapping,
location data, speed issues, load effects, balance calculations,
maneuverability, and other operating issues associated with his sUAS.
Given that trespassers are liable for unintentional intrusions, sUAS
users should spend some time self-educating on these subjects and take
plenty of practice before operating the sUAS near the land of another.
66
This includes a duty to update sUAS software regularly as well as install anti-hacking
and anti-hijacking software. See, e.g., Bryant Jordan, Hacker Releases Software to Hijack
Commercial Drones, DEFENSETECH (Dec. 9, 2013), http://defensetech.org/2013/12/
09/hacker-releases-software-to-hijack-commercial-drones/.
67
While most sUAS have autonomous safety features, it is not uncommon for an sUAS
to fly away or ignore sUAS operator commands, including ascending or descending
beyond desired heights or flying beyond commanded distances. Perritt & Plawinski,
supra note 16 at 320. Indeed, whereas most aircraft have built in redundancies to
reinforce safe flight, sUAS generally lack such safety redundancies.
68
See generally section IV.D. infra.
52 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
B. Private Nuisance
Commercial sUAS users must also be wary of committing private
nuisance. A private nuisance is the “nontrespassory invasion of
another’s interest in the private use and enjoyment of land” that causes
“significant harm.”
69
One is generally subject to liability if his invasion
is “intentional and unreasonable,” or if it is “unintentional or otherwise
actionable under the rules controlling liability for negligent or reckless
conduct . . . .”
70
Like trespass, this tort claim protects an individual’s free enjoyment
of land, but unlike trespass, no physical intrusion is required. Nuisance
also requires that the tortfeasor manifest tortious intent and cause
significant harm, which are not requirements of trespass. The two
claims often overlap, as the same action may constitute both a trespass
and nuisance. As such, a plaintiff may sue in either tort or both.
71
Specifically, nuisance requires significant current or potential harm
“of a kind that would be suffered by a normal person in the community
or by property in normal condition and used for a normal purpose.”
72
There must be a “real and appreciable” interference with a plaintiff’s
interest before he may recover for nuisance.
73
The duration and
frequency of the harm is a significant factor for determining liability.
74
Liability for nuisance also requires some level of tortious intent,
such that the tortfeasor’s action, or omission,
75
must be (1) intentional
and unreasonable, or (2) otherwise negligent or reckless.
76
In
determining liability under either standard of intent, a court will
balance the gravity of the harm against the utility of the activity at
issue.
77
The factors for balancing include, the malicious or indecent
intent of the tortfeasor, the avoidability of the harm, the character of
the harm, the nature of the locality in which the harm is caused, the
social value of the conduct, and the financial burden on the tortfeasor
in compensating for continuing harm.
78
For conduct that is negligent
or reckless, courts balance an additional factor by considering the
magnitude of the risk of harm caused by the conduct.
79
This test
69
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at §§ 821D & F.
70
Id. at § 822 (emphasis omitted).
71
Id. at § 821D cmt. e.
72
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 821F.
73
Id.
74
Id.
75
Id. at § 824.
76
Id. at § 822.
77
Id. at cmt. k; id. at §§ 826-831.
78
Id. at §§ 826-828.
79
Id. at § 822 cmt. k.
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 53
provides courts with broad discretion in determining the liability of an
sUAS user.
Remedies for nuisance include damages for a wide spectrum of
losses, including compensation for physical injury, impairment of
health, personal discomfort, annoyance and inconvenience, cost of
repair of real or personal property, diminished market value of real or
personal property, and lost productivity and rent.
80
Courts will also
award punitive damages and injunctive relief as necessary.
81
This
scheme presents a rich range of judicial choices in balancing outcomes
and awarding relief.
A victim may also be entitled to abate the nuisance.
82
Abatement
possibilities are limited, however, and must be reasonable.
83
Self-help
remedies are permitted only when the nuisance is imminent.
84
A
person must not take abatement actions that are unreasonably
destructive or intrusive.
85
Any mistake about the facts giving rise to a
nuisance, even if reasonable, will not protect a person who acts in
abatement.
86
Small UAS users, therefore, may take some comfort in
the fact that abatement by gunshot will probably not lie for their
nontrespassory sUAS use, even if such use does constitute a nuisance.
Understanding legal precedent for aircraft-related nuisance may be
helpful for sUAS users. Successful aircraft nuisance claims typically
involve aircraft causing dust, noise, light, and vibration, all with
frequency. An sUAS may present the same problems depending on its
use. Small UAS also have distinct capabilities from aircraft and even
remote-controlled airplanes, such as the ability to hover over, follow,
peep on, and record individuals, which make sUAS uniquely intrusive.
In weighing the harm of an sUAS use against its utility, a trier of fact
may find that frequent or long-lasting overflights (or adjacent-flights)
of quiet, residential land during the sleepy hours of the morning
amounts to a nuisance. Small UAS use that periodically frightens
children, startles chickens,
87
or provokes dog barking would likely
subject the user to liability. A trier of fact may also find it particularly
harmful if the sUAS is used to follow an individual, or record video,
sound, or other data concerning a landowner without permission. Such
conduct may be considered contrary to the common standards of
80
See VINCENT R. JOHNSON, STUDIES IN AMERICAN TORT LAW 909 (5th ed. 2013).
81
See id.
82
Id. at 910.
83
Id.
84
Id.
85
Id.
86
Id.
87
Cf. Causby, 328 U.S. 256 (aircraft bothering chickens interfered with use and
enjoyment of land).
54 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
decency, an important factor in the harm-utility balance.
88
Small UAS
users, therefore, should be cognizant of the amount of noise and light
they generate, the type of land they fly over or around, the frequency
with which they fly over or around a parcel of land, the duration of
flight over or around a parcel of land, and in-flight conduct such as
following an individual or data recording.
It is also important for a commercial sUAS user to remember that
he may be liable for unintentional conduct. This means that he may be
liable for failure to understand the operating limitations of his sUAS,
failure to maintain the physical or software integrity of his sUAS, or
for failure to develop and maintain flight knowledge and proficiency;
89
any of which could cause a harmful interference with another’s use and
enjoyment of land.
And, while a commercial sUAS user must cause significant harm to
be liable for nuisance, any harm is unlikely to be outweighed by the
social utility of commercial sUAS use under the pertinent legal
balancing test. Courts have generally found little social utility in profit-
making enterprises absent clear public benefit.
90
Small UAS may
someday confer a clear benefit on the public, but until then, they are
perhaps more like Supreme Court Justice Alexander George
Sutherland’s “pig in a parlor” nuisance,
91
for which the unwary user
will be liable.
C. Invasion of Privacy
If anything, sUAS use challenges society’s sense of privacy, and a
commercial sUAS user may face liability for invading another’s
privacy. Causes of action for privacy invasion have “been useful chiefly
to fill in the gaps left by trespass, nuisance, the intentional infliction
of mental distress, and whatever remedies there may be for the
invasion of constitutional rights.”
92
Privacy invasion consists of four
individual torts: (1) intrusion upon seclusion; (2) appropriation of
another’s name or likeness; (3) public disclosure of private facts; and
(4) false light publicity.
93
While one may easily use an sUAS to
appropriate the name or likeness of another, to obtain and disclose
private facts, or to place another in a false light, it seems that an sUAS
user is most likely to commit the tort of intrusion upon seclusion.
88
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 829.
89
See section III.A., supra.
90
See, e.g., Esposito v. New Britain Baseball Club, Inc., 49 Conn.Sup. 509, 520 (2005)
(fireworks from profit-making entertainment enterprise found less socially beneficial).
91
Vill. of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365, 388 (1926).
92
William L. Prosser, Privacy, 48 CAL. L. REV. 383, 392 (1960).
93
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 652A.
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 55
The Restatement describes a cause of action for intrusion upon
seclusion: "One who intentionally intrudes, physically or otherwise,
upon the solitude or seclusion of another or his private affairs or
concerns, is subject to liability to the other for invasion of his privacy,
if the intrusion would be highly offensive to a reasonable person."
94
The
comments to the Restatement provide that for this tort, (a) there must
be an intentional intrusion; (b) the intrusion may or may not be
physical, may involve the use of senses, with or without mechanical
aids, or may involve some other form of investigation into private
concerns; (c) must involve something that is private; and (d) must be
substantial.
95
This common law tort has been adopted in some form by
most jurisdictions.
96
Under this tort, there is generally no liability for observation while
in public “since [one] is not then in seclusion, and his appearance is
public and open to the public eye.”
97
Certain instances of highly
offensive surveillance in public, however, such as “upskirting”
98
or
recording a victim of a motor vehicle accident,
99
are actionable.
Additionally, close or continued following of an individual, even if that
individual is in public, will subject an sUAS user to privacy liability.
100
In general, intrusion upon seclusion is when someone “interrupts
one’s activities through unwanted [] presence or activities.”
101
For
example, the act of photographing a person at home without his
permission, even when the victim invites the photographer to enter the
home, is an intrusion upon seclusion.
102
In fact, the simple act of
information gathering can constitute intrusion.
103
In some states, no
94
Id. at § 652(B).
95
Id. at cmt. a.-d.
96
Eli A. Meltz, No Harm, No Foul?: “Attempted” Invasion of Privacy and the Tort of
Intrusion upon Seclusion, 83 F
ORDHAM L. REV. 3431 (2015).
97
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 652(B) cmt. c
98
See id.
99
Shulman v. Group W Productions, Inc., 955 P.2d 469 (Cal. 1998) (television program
on emergency response violated privacy rights of victims of motor vehicle accident for
filming accident on scene and in rescue helicopter).
100
See ALISSA M. DOLAN & RICHARD M. THOMPSON II, CONG. RESEARCH SERV., R42949,
I
NTEGRATION OF DRONES INTO DOMESTIC AIRSPACE: SELECTED LEGAL ISSUES, at 19-21
(2015) (citing Galella v. Onassis, 487 F.2d 986, 991-92 (2d Cir. 1973) and noting that
First Amendment will not protect journalists from such invasion of privacy claims); cf.
United States v. Jones, 132 S. Ct. 945, 963 (2012) (law enforcement placing GPS tracking
device on vehicle to follow individual violated reasonable expectation of privacy under
Fourth Amendment).
101
See id.
102
Dietemann v. Time, Inc., 449 F.2d 245, 249 (9th Cir. 1971).
103
See Alexander v. Fed. Bureau of Investigation, 971 F. Supp. 603 (D.D.C. 1997)
(prima facie case for intrusion made against First Lady Hillary Clinton and others based
on gathering of personal information from Federal Bureau of Investigation files).
56 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
observation or actual recording of the information is even necessary for
a cause of action.
104
Mere intent to intrude is sufficient to give rise to
liability.
105
Anyone who intrudes upon the seclusion of another will be liable for
damages for the deprivation of the victim’s seclusion, damages for the
victim’s related emotional distress, and any special damage the victim
can prove.
106
A particularly intrusive sUAS user may be subject to
additional punitive damages.
107
As with other torts, liability for
invasion of privacy case be quite costly, and is something about which
an sUAS user should be keenly aware.
Accordingly, an sUAS user who observes the person, affairs,
concerns, or property of another inside a home or a place reasonably
expected to be private, or just merely intends to do so, is subject to
liability under privacy laws if the invasion is unreasonably offensive.
Similarly, an sUAS user who records data concerning another that is
reasonably expected to be private, or just merely intends to, is subject
to privacy liability. This includes observing or gathering data on an
individual’s physical or virtual whereabouts. As such, it is not difficult
to imagine how the Facebook sUAS,
108
for example, which records an
individual’s internet activity, including imagery, would be liable for a
privacy invasion.
Furthermore, an sUAS user should be careful not to fly too close to
an individual. Such activity, even if well-intentioned, could give rise to
liability, as close flight is more likely to reveal something intimate
about an individual, and the closeness itself may constitute an
intrusion. A commercial sUAS user should also refrain from following
individuals. This includes news media, surveyors, inspectors, and the
like whose activities may inadvertently, or not-so-inadvertently,
amount to nuisance.
Indeed, while liability for intrusion requires an intentional act, even
an “innocent” act could subject the actor to liability. For example, a
building owner may use an sUAS equipped with infrared technology to
inspect a structure. This type of inspection would likely produce a
picture of people inside the building, which may be intrusive.
109
An
104
See Meltz, supra note 96, at 3454-64.
105
See id.
106
RESTATEMENT, supra note 22, at § 652(H).
107
See, e.g., Pulla v. Amoco Oil Co., 882 F. Supp. 836 (S.D. Iowa 1994); see also Prosser,
supra note 92, at 409.
108
See Cade Metz, Facebook’s Giant Internet-Beaming Drone Finally Takes Flight,
W
IRED (July 21, 2016, 12:00 PM), https://www.wired.com/2016/07/facebooks-giant-
internet-beaming-drone-finally-takes-flight/.
109
See Kyllo v. US, 533 US 27, 38 (2001) (According to Supreme Court Justice Antonin
Scalia, law enforcement’s use of heat mapping camera is unconstitutional invasion of
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 57
sUAS user, moreover may be liable even if the intrusion is done with
the intent to benefit the victim.
110
Accordingly, even a well-intentioned
sUAS user should be wary of invading the privacy of another.
D. Other Legal Traps
There are countless other ways in which a commercial sUAS user
could face legal liability. Considering human nature, it is inevitable
that commercial sUAS users will act negligently and cause person
injury or property damage.
111
Indeed, as discussed in sections III.A.
and III.B. supra, a user’s failure to develop and maintain flight
knowledge and proficiency could constitute negligence. It is also
foreseeable that a commercial sUAS user could commit a multitude of
torts ranging from intentional infliction of emotional distress to theft
of trade secrets. In fact, many states and municipalities have enacted
their own specific tort laws addressing sUAS use, increasing an sUAS
user’s potential liability.
112
Some of these states criminalize pertinent
torts. Additional public safety and criminal laws further apply to sUAS
use. Stalking, harassment,
113
voyeurism, assault, battery, smuggling,
computer intrusions, distracting motor vehicle drivers, and
wiretapping are also all real, and likely, applications of an sUAS,
114
and commercial sUAS users should be apprised thereof as well.
Small UAS users should also be wary of “drone zoning,” and other
similar municipal regulations.
115
With the increased use of sUAS, local
regulators may begin to control sUAS use in certain geographic areas.
Localities may regulate the altitude, time, hovering duration, location,
reasonable expectation of privacy, because, among other things, it could reveal whether
the “lady of the house [was taking] her daily . . . bath.”).
110
See, e.g., Huskey v. Nat'l Broad. Co., 632 F. Supp. 1282 (N.D. Ill. 1986)
(documentary crew filming prisoner with intent to improve prison conditions liable for
invasion of prisoner’s privacy.)
111
See, e.g., Kirk Enstrom, Women Sue Groom over Drone Injuries at Wedding
Reception, WMUR (Dec. 8, 2016), http://www.wmur.com/article/women-sue-groom-over-
drone-injuries-at-wedding-reception/8480649 (wedding guests sued photographer for
negligence after being hit by sUAS); Reuters, Drone Crashed into Famed Hot Spring at
Yellowstone National Park (Aug. 7, 2014), http://www.cnbc.com/2014/08/07/drone-
crashes-into-famed-hot-spring-at-yellowstone-national-park.html (negligent sUAS user
loses sUAS in Yellowstone hot spring ).
112
See, e.g., Perritt & Plawinski, supra note 16 at 364-374; Meltz, supra note 96, at
3440-64; Burzichelli, supra note 19 at 182-87.
113
See John Villasenor, Observations from Above: Unmanned Aircraft Systems and
Privacy, 36 H
ARV. J.L. & PUB. POLY, 457, 505-06 (2013) (providing interesting discussion
on sUAS stalking and harassment).
114
DOLAN & THOMPSON, supra note 100, at 29.
115
See Troy A. Rule, Airspace in an Age of Drones, 95. B.U.L REV. 155, 203-07 (2015);
Michael N. Widener, Local Regulating of Drone Activity in Lower Airspace, 22 B.U. J.
S
CI. & TECH. L. 239, 252-60 (2016).
58 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
flight period, flight distance, recording usage, purpose,
116
and other
circumstances of sUAS flight. Some local regulators may ban sUAS
flight within city limits altogether.
117
The multitude of variables
involved in the municipal regulation of sUAS use may present a
complicated algorithm of rules to which an sUAS user must carefully
attend.
IV. AERONAUTICAL TRAPS
Commercial sUAS users must also attend to the recently
promulgated FAA regulations governing sUAS operations. The sUAS
regulations consist of nearly one-hundred provisions, and present a
rich regulatory scheme controlling sUAS use. It is foreseeable that
commercial sUAS users, particularly those who have not undertaken
FAA certificated private pilot training as required under prior law, will
violate any number of regulations. Indeed, the test required obtain an
sUAS remote pilot certificate is much less rigorous than the test
required to obtain a private pilot certificate, and fails prepare
commercial sUAS pilots for proper and compliant use of their aircraft.
As such, unwary sUAS users may be susceptible to violating a handful
of regulations, as highlighted below.
A. Small UAS Aircraft Specifications
Any business that wishes to use an sUAS to enhance its operations
must first register its sUAS,
118
primarily to ensure owner
accountability for legal and regulatory violations. The sUAS itself must
weigh less than fifty-five pounds, including everything that is on board
or attached to it,
119
and may not carry hazardous material.
120
Before
every use, the user must undertake a preflight inspection of the sUAS,
which includes requirements to assess weather conditions, local
airspace, flight restrictions, and potential hazards associated with the
flight.
121
Preflight inspection further requires the sUAS user to ensure
that the sUAS is in proper working order.
122
Small UAS users must
116
For example, a municipality may ban the use of sUAS for aerial advertising. Cf.
Skysign International, Inc. v. City and County of Honolulu, 276 F.3d 1109 (9th Cir. 2002)
(local regulation of signage could be applied to banner-towing aircraft).
117
Evanston, Illinois has banned commercial sUAS use within city limits and St.
Bonaficius, Minnesota has banned all types of sUAS use within city limits, including
recreational use. Robert H. Gruber, Commercial Drones and Privacy: Can We Trust
States with “Drone Federalism”?, 21 R
ICH. J.L. & TECH. 14, 21 (2015).
118
FAR, supra note 2, at § 107.13.
119
Id. at § 107.3.
120
Id. at § 107.36.
121
Id. at § 107.49(a).
122
Id. at § 107.15 & § 107.49(c)-(e).
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 59
also advise anyone participating in the operation of the operating
conditions, emergency procedures, roles and responsibilities, and
potential hazards related thereto prior to flight.
123
Failure to comply with any of these specifications would subject an
sUAS user to regulatory liability. The required assessment of weather,
airspace, flight restrictions, and hazards is particularly complicated
and time-consuming, and is an area where a commercial sUAS user
would be highly vulnerable to liability. Weather is a sophisticated
science, and a proper assessment of weather conditions will require the
user to identify and interpret specially published aviation weather
charts and data. Similarly, the NAS is complex, and an sUAS user
must decode current aeronautical charts, airport facility directories,
and other supplements and apply them to his planned flight. An sUAS
user must also obtain recent Notices to Airmen, which include time-
critical aeronautical information concerning potential airspace
hazards and restrictions, including Temporary Flight Restrictions
(TFRs),
124
that may be relevant to their flight path. Flight planning
takes time, and it is easy to see how a commercial sUAS user, whose
time is quantifiable in money, may be tempted to check weather.com
and Google Maps to prepare for flight, and neglect the other, more
onerous, requirements. An sUAS user must not succumb to such
temptation, however, as it would subject him to both regulatory and
tort liability.
125
B. Small UAS User Specifications
To operate an sUAS, a user must be at least sixteen years of age,
126
and pass an aeronautical knowledge test to obtain a remote pilot
certificate with an sUAS rating.
127
The user must also pass recurrent
knowledge tests every twenty-four months.
128
The regulations further
provide that no person may operate an sUAS if he has a physical or
123
Id. at § 107.49(b).
124
A TFR defines a certain area of airspace where air travel is limited because of
temporary hazardous conditions, such as a wildfire or rescue operation; a security-
related event, like air travel by the US President; or other special situation, like a Super
Bowl. J
EPPESEN, supra note 34, at 4-77. TFRs are updated perpetually throughout a day,
and a pilot must always check them immediately prior to flight. See generally id. at 7-
45.
125
For example, failure to understand airspace could easily cause a trespass. Failure
to consult appropriate weather sources would constitute negligence. Both situations
could also present a nuisance.
126
FAR, supra note 2, at §107.61.
127
Id.
128
Id. at §107.65.
60 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
mental condition that would interfere with its safe operation.
129
And,
an sUAS user may be surprised to learn that he may not fly an sUAS
within eight hours of having even a taste of alcohol.
130
Other than an occasional, but predictable, user neglecting his
recurrent testing requirement, the primary concern with respect to the
sUAS user specifications is the requirement that the user not have a
compromising medical condition. This regulation is unlike the medical
requirements for a private pilot, which provide a list of medical
conditions that would disqualify a candidate for a licensing
certificate.
131
For sUAS operation, a user would have to self-validate
his safe medical condition, which, if done imprudently, would subject
him to regulatory liability. An imprudent self-evaluation of an sUAS
user would further subject him to tort and other liability if his medical
condition led him to trespass, cause nuisance, invade privacy, operate
his sUAS negligently, or commit some other legal transgression.
C. Small UAS Timing Specifications
FAA regulations specify that a user must not operate an sUAS at
night, and require special anti-collision lighting during civil twilight.
132
In addition, an sUAS user may only fly when there is minimum flight
visibility of no less than three statute miles as observed from the
location of his control station.
133
Visibility is measured by the average
slant distance from the control station at which prominent objects may
be identified.
134
While these specifications present easy compliance, it may be
challenging for an sUAS user to measure visibility. Aviation weather
sources provide data with respect to horizontal visibility, which may
differ from the slant visibility that sUAS users must assess. While
private pilots are specifically trained to measure visibility, as well as
to identify when visibility becomes diminished, sUAS users lack this
training and could easily miscalculate visibility. Flying under
conditions with compromised visibility is not only a regulatory
violation, but, for all the reasons stated herein, could also effect a
trespass, nuisance, negligence, or other tort violation.
129
Id. at § 107.17.
130
Id. at § 91.17. An sUAS user must also not have a concentration of 0.04 or greater
grams of alcohol per deciliter of blood or per 210 liters of breath. Id.
131
Id. at §§ 67.1 – 67.415.
132
Id. § 107.29. Except for in Alaska, civil twilight is a period of time that begins thirty
minutes before official sunrise and ends at official sunrise, and a period of time that
begins at official sunset and ends thirty minutes after official sunset. Id. at § 107.29(c).
133
Id. at § 107.51.
134
Id. at § 107.51(c).
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 61
D. Small UAS Location Specifications
An sUAS user must operate his aircraft within his visual line-of-
sight.
135
This means that an sUAS must always remain within sight of
the remote pilot or designated visual observer. Small UAS users must
refrain from flying over any person not participating in the
operation.
136
In addition, an sUAS may not be flown higher than 400
feet AGL or the highest point of a structure,
137
and must remain 500
feet below clouds and 2,000 feet horizontally from clouds.
138
A remote
sUAS pilot must also not enter “controlled,”
139
prohibited or
restricted
140
airspace without permission from Air Traffic Control, and
must not operate in the vicinity of an airport in manner that interferes
with its operations.
141
An sUAS flight carrying property for
compensation must remain intrastate.
142
Of all sUAS regulations, it seems that for a variety of reasons, sUAS
users are most likely to violate location specifications. First, the test
for sUAS pilot certification does not require practical training or
aeronautical experience. It is easy to see how an inexperienced remote
pilot could violate any one of the location specifications without
training or experience on how to aviate.
Second, it may be impossible for an sUAS user to refrain from flying
over any people. This is particularly true if an sUAS operation is being
conducted in a congested or urban area. An sUAS user may obtain from
the FAA a waiver of this requirement, but must follow a specified
procedure including providing a complete description of the proposed
operation, and establishing that the operation can safely be conducted
in the event of a waiver.
143
Given the difficulties of avoiding flight over
any people at all times, sUAS users may have to request multiple
waivers to avoid violating this regulation. Multiple requests may
become overly burdensome, and lead to risky noncompliance.
Third, the knowledge test for the remote pilot certificate with an
sUAS rating fails to prepare a user to assess sufficiently his location.
The knowledge test does not test pilotage or “dead reckoning” skills.
135
Id. at § 107.31.
136
Id. at § 107.39.
137
Id. at § 107.51(b).
138
Id. at § 107.51(d).
139
Id. at § 107.41. This means that an sUAS may not operate in Class B, C, or D
airspace, or within the lateral boundaries of the surface area of Class E airspace
designated for an airport.
140
Id. at § 107.45.
141
Id. at § 107.43.
142
See 49 U.S.C. 40102(a)(2) (defining “air carrier”) and (a)(5) (defining “air
transportation”).
143
Id. at § 107.200.
62 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Pilotage is the skill of understanding aircraft location by reading an
aeronautical chart or supplement and comparing it with the
surrounding terrain.
144
Dead reckoning is the process by which pilots
determine their location and effect navigation using time, speed,
distance, and direction without the aid of advanced technology, such as
a GPS or other computer-assisted information system.
145
While most
popular commercial sUAS have GPS and other systems to inform the
user of its location, it is not uncommon for such systems to fail. In such
a case, an sUAS user without pilotage and dead reckoning skills would
likely be unable to determine accurately his location, and make him
vulnerable to violating several of the aforementioned FAA regulations.
Furthermore, the sUAS test fails to prepare users to assess their
altitude independent of a GPS or other similar system. While most
commercial sUAS provide the user with altitude data, and some even
verbally alert the user when nearing a maximum specified altitude, not
all sUAS have altitude-encoding equipment. Without training, an
sUAS user must estimate his altitude, which is a challenging
assignment with a device at hundreds of feet in the air. Private pilots
also learn that there are also many atmospheric, weather, topographic,
lighting, and other conditions that can lead one to misgauge the
altitude of an object in the air. Without training or experience, sUAS
pilots are not likely to be able to determine the precise altitude of their
sUAS without a GPS. Further, the sUAS altitude requirement is given
in AGL, whereas aeronautical charts and aids provide many altitudes
in MSL. While the sUAS knowledge test does briefly discuss the
difference in altitude measurements, this disparity can still pose
problems for a novice pilot.
The sUAS knowledge test, moreover, fails to prime a user on in-
flight weather observation and data-gathering. Private pilots are
trained on how to identify and obtain flight-altering weather conditions
during the course of flight. Weather conditions can change abruptly,
and ultimately force an aircraft to run outside of its operating
limitations. Private pilots are therefore trained on how to interpret in-
flight weather data and observations to avoid potentially dangerous
conditions. Remote sUAS pilots, however, are not required to develop
these skills, even though they may also encounter adverse weather
conditions. Adverse weather can cause a pilot to misunderstand his
location (e.g., upon entering fast-advancing clouds), or worse, be unable
to operate his sUAS safely, thereby posing a danger to people and
property on the ground.
144
JEPPESEN, supra note 34, at 9-7.
145
Id. at 9-7, – 9-8.
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 63
For the same reasons, sUAS users will initially lack the ability to
gauge their distance from the clouds. This may cause the sUAS to enter
the clouds errantly, which is an instant violation of several FAA
regulations.
146
Once in the clouds, the sUAS user may easily lose his
understanding of his location. More significantly, however, an sUAS
user that misgauges his distance from the clouds presents a serious
collision danger to other aircraft that may be flying in the clouds or
exiting from the clouds at high rates of speed. Other aircraft may be
unable to see an sUAS that is operating in the clouds, and vice versa,
and neither may have time to avoid the other.
The sUAS knowledge test also fails to prepare an sUAS user on
many other aspects of flight that would enhance his understanding of
his location and remote piloting in general. For example, an sUAS user
is not tested on subjects like obstacle clearance requirements,
principles of flight, aerodynamics, and electrical theory. Private pilots
are tested on all of these subjects, the knowledge of which aid in their
regulatory and legal compliance.
Thus, for a variety of reasons, an sUAS user could misapprehend his
location, and violate any number of FAA regulations. Misgauging
location could cause an sUAS user to wander over people, above a
permitted altitude, too close to clouds, into busy controlled airspace, in
prohibited or restricted airspace, in the vicinity of an airport
interfering with its operations, and across state lines. A lost sUAS user
could also errantly wander into warning areas, military operation
areas, alert areas, controlled firing areas, low altitude Military
Training Routes, areas subject to special TFRs, Parachute Jump
Operations, National Security Areas, Visual Flight Rule Routes, and
Instrument Flight Rule Routes. Such wandering also presents a risk of
tort liability, which includes not just the obvious exposure to trespass
and nuisance claims, but also the serious danger of collision with other
aircraft that could cause significant personal injury and property
damage.
E. Small UAS Operational Specifications
The FAA also provides a list of operational prohibitions about which
sUAS users should be informed. In particular, a user should not
operate an sUAS in a careless or reckless manner,
147
including
operating over eighty-seven knots, or one-hundred miles-per hour.
148
A
user may not operate more than one sUAS at a time,
149
and may
146
See, e.g., id. at §§ 107.51(d); 107.31.
147
Id. at § 107.23(a).
148
Id. at § 107.51(a).
149
Id. at § 107.35.
64 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
generally not operate an sUAS from a moving vehicle or aircraft.
150
If
the sUAS is involved in an accident, a user must report it to the FAA
within ten days if the accident resulted in serious personal injury or
property damage over $500.
151
A commercial sUAS user should be able to comply easily with most
operational specifications, although the “careless or reckless” operation
standard is ostensibly vague. Failure to undertake a thorough preflight
examination, failure to ascertain weather conditions, failure to become
proficient in flight skills and knowledge or maintain proficiency
thereof, failure to maintain the sUAS, as well as failure to update, and
understand updates of, sUAS software might all constitute careless or
reckless operation. It may also be difficult for an untrained sUAS user
to comply with groundspeed restrictions, particularly if his sUAS does
not provide groundspeed data, or its groundspeed systems become
dysfunctional. Absent practical training, it is difficult to determine the
groundspeed of an object in the air, and one can imagine a situation in
which a novice commercial sUAS user would miscalculate his speed
and violate this and other related regulations, as well as face potential
tort liability therefrom.
F. Penalties for Regulatory Violations
Violation of any of the aforementioned sUAS regulations could
subject an sUAS user to significant sanctions. It should be noted that
the FAA has indicated its intention to promulgate addition regulations
governing sUAS, which would further expose sUAS users to potential
sanctions.
152
Small UAS users are also subject to numerous other FAA
regulations by virtue of being an “aircraft,” which may subject them to
additional sanctions.
153
In determining sanctions for any regulatory violation, the FAA
weighs several factors, including, but not limited to, the severity of the
safety risk involved, the number of pre- and co-existing regulatory and
legal violations, whether the violation involved careless or reckless
conduct, aggravating and mitigating circumstances, the ability of the
violator to absorb the sanction, and the consistency of the sanction.
154
Sanctions include administrative actions such as a “Warning Notice”
150
Id. at § 107.25.
151
Id. at § 107.9.
152
Operation and Certification of Small Unmanned Aircraft Systems, 81 Fed.
Reg.42063 at 27-28 & 37 (2016) (to be codified at 14 C.F.R. pts. 21, 43, 61, 91, 101, 107,
119, 133, & 183) [hereinafter Part 107 Preamble].
153
Id. at 39-42.
154
See FAA, Compliance and Enforcement Program, F.A.A. Order No. 2150.3B, at ch.
7 & app. B. (2015) [hereinafter Enforcement Handbook].
2017 / Traps for the Unwary Commercial Drone User / 65
or a “Letter of Correction,”
155
certificate suspensions or revocations,
and civil penalties that range from $100 to $500,000 per violation.
156
Commercial sUAS users should be wary of violating FAA
regulations, particularly given the FAA’s recent aggressive
enforcement action against SkyPan International, Inc. (“SkyPan”).
SkyPan is an aerial photographer who apparently flew an sUAS above
private property, mostly consisting of dirt, grass, or paved lots, to assist
land developers with design plans for new buildings.
157
The FAA
accused SkyPan of flying without a Section 333 exemption (under
previous law), and violating Class B airspace, among other things, and
proposed a civil penalty against SkyPan of $11,000 per violation for a
total of $1.9 million.
158
A regulatory violation may not only demand prohibitive fines; it may
also constitute negligence per se, subjecting an sUAS user to automatic
tort liability in addition to administrative liability. Even if a violation
is not negligence per se, it is likely that activities that violate FAA
regulations would also amount to the commission of any number of
torts for which an sUAS user would be additionally liable. And, while
a sUAS user may successfully defeat FAA enforcement and coincident
tort liability, the user will likely have to spend tens of thousands of
dollars, or more, in defense costs. It is best, therefore for sUAS users
to be mindful of FAA regulations.
V. CONCLUSION
The market for commercial sUAS use is exploding, and there are
likely to be millions of commercial sUAS flying around by the year
2020. Commercial sUAS are becoming more affordable and more
useful, and the recent changes to the law make it easier to obtain a
remote pilot license for sUAS operation. Most commercial sUAS users,
however, will lack understanding of both law and aviation, and many
unwary users will face the legal and aeronautical traps discussed
herein. Tort and property lawsuits are inevitable, as are regulatory
violations.
155
FAR § 13.11. A “Letter of Correction” states the necessary corrective action the
alleged violator agrees to take. If the agreed corrective action is not fully completed, legal
enforcement action may be taken.
156
See Enforcement Handbook, supra note 154.
157
See SkyPan International Inc., Docket No. FAAï2014ï1102 at 1 (FAA Apr. 17, 2015),
available at https://www.faa.gov/uas/beyond_the_basics/section_333/333_authorizations/
media/skypan_international_11352.pdf.
158
Press Release, FAA, FAA Proposes $1.9 Million Civil Penalty Against SkyPan
International for Allegedly Unauthorized Unmanned Aircraft Operations (Oct. 6, 2015),
available at https://www.faa.gov/news/press_releases/news_story.cfm?newsId=19555.
66 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Liability risks for sUAS users, moreover, are likely to grow in the
future. There will be more state and local laws governing sUAS, and
the FAA intends to promulgate additional regulations relative to
sUAS. Significantly, businesses should not assume that insurance will
cover any liability associated with their sUAS use.
159
It is important, therefore, for a commercial sUAS user to understand
the applicable legal and regulatory hazards. To avoid liability,
commercial sUAS users should spend time with competent legal
counsel to discuss the legal and regulatory issues discussed above. And,
in addition to the FAA recommended twenty hours of self-study,
160
sUAS users should spend some time with a Certified Flight Instructor
to review the NAS, weather, pilotage and dead reckoning, performance
issues, airport operations, aeronautical decision-making, common
safety practices, and the culture of aviation. Responsible attention to,
and careful study of, all the aforementioned issues should mitigate the
risk of the potentially costly tort and regulatory liability associated
with commercial sUAS use.
159
Cf. Tom Schrimpf & Russ Klingaman, Recreational Drones: Do Homeowners’
Insurance Policies Provide Coverage?, C
LAIMS J. (Aug. 4, 2015)
http://www.claimsjournal.com/news/national/2015/08/04/264918.htm (noting policies
exclude coverage for damage associated with “aircraft” use).
160
Part 107 Preamble, supra note 152, at 551.
STICK ‘EM UP THIS IS A BREACH: A CASE FOR
PUNITIVE DAMAGES FOR CONTRACT HOLDUPS
by Scott Thomas,
*
David Missirian
**
and Mystica Alexander
***
I. INTRODUCTION
Consider the following fact pattern. After lengthy negotiations, the
parties finally arrive at terms to a contract. Before the parties
complete their obligations under the contract, one party makes a
midterm demand to renegotiate the contract using the threat of a
breach of contract to increase her bargaining power in negotiating a
new contract or modifications to an existing contract. We see these
scenarios repeatedly. Superstar athletes hold out in a demand for
contract renegotiation, a consumer of services withholds payment after
services have been provided in the hope of getting a price reduction, or
a vendor decides to sell promised goods to a third party unless the
customer pays a higher price. Corbin has used the phrase “holdup” to
refer to these types of situations.
1
Holdup is a fitting term for this
behavior, since the behavior, in its own right, justifies the term and the
victims are often limited to recovery of foreseeable compensatory
damages.
Traditionally, courts have held the purpose of contract damages is
to compensate the victim of a breach for injury. These damages often
address three different interests held by the nonbreaching party:
expectation interest, reliance interest, and restitution interest.
*
Lecturer, Bentley University
**
Assistant Professor, Bentley University
***
Assistant Professor, Bentley University
1
IA A. CORBIN, CORBIN ON CONTRACTS § 171, at 105 (1963).
68 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Protecting the plaintiff’s restitution interest means the defendant
should return any benefit the plaintiff conferred. Protecting the
plaintiff’s reliance interest requires the reimbursement of the plaintiff
for losses sustained in reliance on the contract, returning the plaintiff
to her position prior to the contract. This paper focuses on the
awarding of expectation damages to put the nonbreaching party where
she would have been if the contract had been performed and concludes
these damages are insufficient.
2
In the awarding of damages,
expectation damages usually exceed reliance damages, which often
exceed damages awarded for restitution. Courts have generally been
reluctant to provide a plaintiff with an award beyond these three
measures of damages. More specifically, punitive damages have
generally not been available in contract actions. As stated in Section
355 of the Restatement (Second) of Contracts: “Punitive damages are
not recoverable for a breach of contract unless the conduct constituting
the breach is also a tort for which punitive damages are recoverable.
3
However, in cases of a willful breach of contract, in which the
breaching party seeks to better her position through the breach, the
traditional measure of damages seems to fall short, and punitive
damages could serve as a well-needed deterrent to such behavior.
Unfortunately, dismissing or ignoring ethical reasons for deterring
holdups, the courts and commentators have often justified limiting
recovery to expectation damages using economic theory, social policy,
and existing commercial law doctrine.
This paper explores these economic, social, and ethical theories. Part
II provides a more detailed look at typical holdup scenarios. Part III
discusses the economic theories and social theories used by courts
when limiting damage awards. Part IV explores the ethical
dimensions of contractual agreements and the ethical implications of
“bad behavior.” Ultimately, this paper concludes that justice is best
served by the awarding of punitive damages to victims of a holdup.
II. UNDERSTANDING HOLDUPS IN THE COMMERCIAL
SETTING
A holdup can occur in many forms and ultimately leads to the
encouragement of breaches when courts limit their awards to
expectation damages. Consider more closely the impact of the
superstar athlete and the service recipient engaging in a willful breach.
A superstar athlete is in his third year of a four-year contract.
Hoping for a contract extension, the superstar refuses to attend
2
Robert Cooter and Melvin Aron Eisenberg, Damages for Breach of Contract, 73 CAL.
L. REV. 1432 (1985), http://scholarship.law.berkeley.edu/facpubs/1449 .
3
RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 355 (1981).
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 69
practices and to play in exhibition games until his contract is
renegotiated. Faced with this predicament, ownership stands in the
shoes of the holdup victim and often finds little relief from the courts.
One commentator has explained the mechanics and bargaining power
of a holdout as follows:
Owners will sign a marquee player to a long-term deal to please fans
and promote team stability. However, certain players elect to try to
coerce ownership into renegotiating existing contracts before the
contractual term has expired. These players, usually perennial all-
stars at the prime of their careers, will announce, likely during the
off-season, that they will “hold out” from training camp and the
upcoming season unless their contract is modified to reflect their “true
value.” When negotiations reach a stalemate, the player will follow
through on his threat and refuse to participate with the team.
4
One of the reasons a player’s threat to hold out is so powerful is that
the legal remedies available to a team against a superstar are sorely
lacking.
5
At best, a team can secure a “negative injunction” to prevent
a player from playing professionally for another sports franchise. It is
“exceedingly burdensome to establish what the loss of one player, even
a superstar player, will have on the clubs performance and its financial
condition.”
6
As a result of these limitations, owners have not
successfully litigated a claim for damages against an athlete.
7
The
difficulty of reaching a suitable calculation of damages also undercuts
the likely effectiveness of some of the more creative solutions to the
holdout problems proposed by commentators, such as the use of
tortious breach of contract litigation.
8
The punitive damages proposed
have often relied on the establishment of an independent tort.
9
As a
result, these superstars better their positions for the remaining years
on their contracts with no adequate damages left for the nonbreaching
owners. Left with the burden of proving damages and disappointed
fans, the owner becomes a victim of the holdup. The player’s
opportunistic behavior increases his slice of the pie, and the owner
receives no compensation. Punitive damages for breach of contract
4
Basil M. Loeb, Comment, Deterring Player Holdouts: Who Should Do It, How to Do
It, and Why It Has to be Done, 11 M
ARQ. SPORTS L. REV. 275, 275 (2001).
5
See generally Alex M. Johnson, Jr., The Argument for Self-Help Specific
Performance: Opportunistic Renegotiation of Player Contracts, 22 C
ONN. L. REV. 61
(1989).
6
Id. at 78.
7
Id. at 81.
8
Kevin Yeam, New Remedial Developments in the Enforcement of Personal Services
Contracts for the Entertainment and Sports Industries: The Rise of Tortious Bad Faith
of Contract and the Fall of the Speculative Damages Defense, 7 L
OY. L.A. ENT. L.J. 27
(1987).
9
Id.
70 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
could level the playing field and discourage this type of opportunistic
breach.
Another frustrating opportunistic breach is a bad faith refusal to
pay. A service provider spends months learning the business of a
client, presents the client with a contract that is negotiated by the
attorneys for several weeks, the services occur over a year, and the
client accepts the services as fully in compliance with the contract.
However, the client, fully aware of its negotiating leverage, refuses to
pay. This could occur when the client has other contracts with the
organization, leaving the service provider fearful those contracts could
suffer. This could also occur in situations where suing clients in a
small professional community could damage the service provider’s
reputation, despite the strong validity of the claim. When considering
these types of breaches, one court has expressly held that an “obstinate
and willful refusal to pay . . . is a ground upon which punitive damages
may legitimately be granted.”
10
But this is highly unusual, and even
some states that generally allow punitive damages for breach of
contract deny such damages for willful refusal to pay a debt.
11
III. CHARACTERIZING THE BREACH AND RATIONALIZING
THE LIMITATION OF DAMAGES
Analyzing the appropriate damage award for a willful breach
requires consideration of the economic and social implications of such
a breach. After describing the types of willful breaches of contracts and
the legal history, this part explores each of these areas and the unique
considerations applicable to each type of willful breach.
A. Types of Willful Breach
Commentators have divided willful breaches into two categories:
opportunistic and efficient. “A breach is opportunistic if the breaching
party attempts to get more than he bargained for at the expense of the
nonbreaching party.”
12
An opportunistic breach would include the
holdup described above where a party refuses to pay for properly
performed services merely to obtain a price reduction. The breaching
party improves her position at the expense of the nonbreaching party.
An efficient breach improves the position of the breaching party but
gives the benefit of the contract to the nonbreaching party through the
payment of expectation damages. An efficient breach example would
10
DynaSteel Corp. v. Aztec Indus., 611 So. 2d 977, 984 (Miss. 1992).
11
See, e.g., Vann v. Nationwide Ins. Co., 185 S.E.2d 363, 364 (S.C. 1971) (“Punitive
damages are not recoverable for the mere failure or refusal to pay a debt.”).
12
See William S. Dodge, The Case for Punitive Damages in Contracts, 48 DUKE L. J.
629, 652 (1999).
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 71
include finding another customer willing to pay more for your product
and breaching your contract for the sale of those goods to the
nonbreaching party, but paying expectation damages to the
nonbreaching party. Therefore, proponents of efficient breaches would
argue that it creates a “Pareto improvement” whereby the breaching
party is better off and neither party suffers from the breach.
13
In other
words, an opportunistic breach slices the pie into different size
portions, while an efficient breach increases the overall size of the pie.
Despite placing these two breaching parties in different camps, where
one is being labelled as an opportunistic breacher, the presumably bad
seed, and the other as merely being an efficient breacher, the
presumably good seed, let it not be lost that both of these parties broke
their promise to perform.
B. Damages for a Willful Breach
Although punitive damages have traditionally been awarded in tort
actions, the long-standing presumption of lawyers and scholars alike
is that punitive damages should not be awarded for a breach of
contract.
14
What are the origins of this presumption and is this
presumption, in fact, accurate? To understand the law’s approach to
punitive damages, it is necessary to view this in the context of the
origin of contracts, the origin of punitive damages, and the objectives
served by the award of such damages.
1. Historical Background:
Our modern understanding of contracts has its origins in the
nineteenth century.
15
While the medieval understanding of
contractual relationships was rooted in the idea of “inherent injustice”
or “fairness of an exchange” that prevailed through the eighteenth
century, the nineteenth century witnessed a departure from this
approach as courts and jurists both in England and the United States
established that “the source of obligation of contract is the convergence
of the wills of the contracting parties.
16
Traditionally, contract
remedies seek to compensate a non-breaching party for harm suffered,
and do not seek to compel the breaching party to perform.
17
13
E. FARNSWORTH, CONTRACTS §1.2 at 7, note 1 (1982).
14
Timothy J. Sullivan, Punitive Damages in the Law of Contract: The Reality and the
Illusion of Legal Change, 61 M
INN. L. REV. 207 (1977).
15
Morton J. Horwitz, The Historical Foundations of Modern Contract Law, 87
H
ARVARD L. REV. 917 (1974).
16
Id.
17
Dodge, supra note 12, at 630.
72 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
A look at the system of justice in Medieval England indicates that
by the end of the reign of King Henry III in 1272, the King’s Court had
not yet developed a doctrine of contract law.
18
A loose notion of
contract law indicated that it was limited to cases in which a defendant
had received either something tangible or services from a plaintiff for
which he failed to pay.
19
In this early time period we see the court
either imposing punishment for crimes committed, or providing
specific relief to a plaintiff for harm suffered.
20
“The plaintiff’s
objective was not to receive a judgment for some pecuniary sum but
rather to obtain a judicial declaration establishing his entitlement to
the return of some species of property of which he had been deprived.
21
It was only gradually during the thirteenth century that there arose a
suggestion that it may be possible to recover a “double remedy.”
22
“This
can be attributed to the rise of trespass actions which would set the
law on a path to making “the award of pecuniary compensation
commonplace in Anglo-American law.”
23
Interestingly, punitive damages trace their origins in English law to
juror sentiment rather than to any specific legislative or judicial
actions. Although there was precedent for setting the amount of
damages based on some fixed schedule,
24
the King’s Court rejected this
approach in the assessment of damages, choosing instead to vest
responsibility for this in the jury.
25
For example, punitive damages
were awarded in 1769 to an individual whose unmarried daughter was
impregnated by the defendant. The court made note that the jury was
right to award liberal damages, and that the court would have
approved of an even greater amount because the plaintiff received this
insult from the defendant “in his own house.”
26
English law did not prescribe rules for juries on how a damage
award can/should be assessed, and so jury assessments were
sometimes excessive and sometimes inadequate.
27
In the absence of
substantive law, the courts found procedural means to control damage
18
F. POLLOCK & F. MAITLAND, THE HISTORY OF ENGLISH LAW 194 (2d. ed. 1898).
http://socserv2.socsci.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/maitland/HistoryEnglishLaw2.pdf
(Cambridge University Press, Cambridge).
19
Pollock, supra note 18, at 222.
20
Id. at 523.
21
Sullivan, supra note 14, at 208.
22
Pollock, supra note 18, at 524.
23
Sullivan, supra note 14, at 208-209.
24
Pollock, supra note 18, at 457-458.
25
Sullivan, supra note 14, at 209.
26
Tullidge v. Wade, 95 Eng. Rep. 909 (K.B. 1769).
27
Sullivan, supra note 14, at 210.
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 73
awards.
28
For example, in the thirteenth century the “writ of attaint”
was developed. This could be used to either set aside an erroneous
verdict but also punish any jury that rendered a false verdict. This
short-lived approach gradually gave way to other methods of
controlling a jury verdict, so that in 1655, in the case of Wood v.
Gunston,
29
the court ruled a new trial could be awarded to a defendant
solely as a result of an excessive damage award.
30
Although in this case
the King’s Court established the authority of the court to grant a new
trial on the ground of excessive damages, it is important to note this
rule was not applied equally to tort and contract cases. Judges were
less likely to interfere with damage awards for tortious conduct than
for contract damages.
31
So here we see the beginning of a distinction
for damages in contracts actions as opposed to those involving tortious
behavior.
By the early nineteenth century, punitive damages, especially in
tort actions, were an accepted part of English law. This sentiment
carried over to the American legal system. By the mid-nineteenth
century punitive damages in tort were well-settled law, although not
without some controversy and disparity as to the limitations of such
awards.
32
Much like their English predecessors, early American jurists
generally did not provide jury instructions on damages awards, nor did
they ordinarily take action to adjust a damage award they found
disagreeable.
33
Such action confirmed the early view of contracts cases
as equitable in nature, ruled by the prevailing standard of the
“community’s sense of fairness.
34
Early court decisions in colonial
Virginia and South Carolina illustrate the jurist’s deference to the
jury’s award of damages.
35
As time progressed, a different approach to
contract law began to be adopted, the effects of which we see in The
Restatement (First) of Contracts description of the purposes of
contracts damages: “Where a right of action for breach exists,
compensatory damages will be given for the net amount of the losses
caused and gains prevented by the defendant’s breach.”
36
There is a
28
Id.
29
82 Eng. Rep. 867 (K.B. 1655).
30
Sullivan, supra note14, at 212.
31
Id. at 212-213.
32
Id. at 215.
33
Horwitz, supra note 15, at 925.
34
Id.
35
Id., citing Pledger v. Wade, 1 Bay 35, 37 (S.C. 1786) (South Carolina Supreme Court
will not award a new trial even though the jury verdict was for a lesser amount that the
contract price), and Waugh v. Bagg, 1 Virginia Colonial Decisions 77, 78 (Va., 1731)
(excess damages awarded by a jury was not grounds for a new trial).
36
RESTATEMENT OF CONTRACTS §329 (1932).
74 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
movement away from the notion of fairness and justice to one of putting
a party back to where one started absent the breach. The simplistic
notion of putting a party back to its position before the breach has
inherent appeal, but can an action ever truly be undone or reversed as
to all of its consequences and ramifications?
2. Contemporary Understanding of Contract Damages:
The Restatement (Second) of Contracts makes clear the prevailing
approach with regard to availability of punitive damages: “Punitive
damages are not recoverable for a breach of contract unless the conduct
constituting the breach is also a tort for which punitive damages are
recoverable.”
37
There are a few exceptions to the rule barring punitive
damages for breach of contract: breach of a contract by a public service
company,
38
breach of a contract that is also a breach of a fiduciary
duty,
39
breach of a contract to marry,
40
and bad faith breach of an
insurance contract.
41
For a brief period of time, in the 1970s and 1980s, the U.S. witnessed
a more liberal approach to punitive damages awards with various
jurisdictions “allowing plaintiffs to recover punitive damages directly
in contract actions and others achieving the same result by
characterizing some contractual breaches as torts.
42
However, since
the end of the 1980s courts have generally retreated from this
expansion of punitive damage awards to once again focus on the
compensatory nature of contract damages.
43
Although rarely allowed in contract cases, the U.S. Supreme Court
has defined the contemporary function of punitive damages as
punishment and deterrence.
44
37
RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS §355 (1981).
38
See, e.g., Stevenson v. John J. Grier Hotel Co., 251 S.W. 355, 355 (Ark. 1923); Milner
Hotels v. Brent, 43 So. 2d 654, 656 (Miss. 1949).
39
See, e.g., Brown v. Coates, 253 F.2d 36, 40 (D.C. Cir. 1958); Newton v. Hornblower,
Inc., 582 P.2d 1136, 1149 (Kan. 1978); Balsemides v. Perle, 712 A.2d 673, 685 (N.J.
Super. Ct. App. Div. 1998).
40
Coryell v. Colbaugh, 1 N.J.L. 90, 91 (N.J. 1791).
41
At least 45 states recognize bad faith breach of an insurance contract as a tort in
third-party cases. See Douglas R. Richmond, An Overview of Insurance Bad Faith Law
and Litigation, 25 S
ETON HALL L. REV. 74, 80 n.33 (1994) (listing cases).
42
Dodge, supra note 12, at 638. See, for example Barry Perlstein, Crossing the
Contract-Tort Boundary: An Economic Argument for the Imposition of
Extracompensatory Damages for Opportunistic Breach of Contract, 58 B
ROOKLYN L. REV.
877 (1992) (discussing a line of California cases that have concluded that acting in bad
faith is a breach of the implied covenant of fair dealing in a contract).
43
Dodge, supra note 12, at 642.
44
Smith v. Wade, 461 U.S. 30 (1983).
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 75
Punitive damages are awarded in the jury’s discretion “to punish [the
defendant] for his outrageous conduct and to deter him and others like
him from similar conduct in the future.” Restatement (Second) of
Torts Sec. 908(1) (1979). The focus is on the character of the
tortfeasor’s conduct – whether it is of the sort that calls for deterrence
and punishment over and above that provided by compensatory
awards. If it is of such a character, then it is appropriate to allow a
jury to assess punitive damages … To put it differently, society has an
interest in deterring and punishing all intentional or reckless
invasions of the rights of others, even though it sometimes chooses not
to impose any liability for lesser degrees of fault.
45
C. Economic Rationale for Limiting Damages:
We find little discussion regarding the reluctance of our courts to
award damages that go beyond expectation damages. Instead, the
courts appear to have avoided any discussion of the benefits that
punitive damages could bring in maintaining the sanctity of contracts.
[O]ne of the principal impediments to analysis of contract cases
treating the question of punitive damages is the consistent absence,
particularly in the early cases, of any meaningful judicial discussion
of the philosophy of damage law.... Whatever the explanation, we
must begin without any firm idea of why, beyond adherence to
traditional English standards, American courts have held, as a
general rule, that punitive damages should not be awarded for breach
of contract.
46
In Iron Mountain Security Storage v. American Specialty Foods,
Inc.,
47
a federal district court provided insight with respect to damage
limitations involving contracts. Although this case involved a tort
lawsuit for a violation of the implied covenant of good faith and fair
dealing, it gave us a sense of the thinking of the courts at that time.
The court refused to extend tort liability beyond insurance contracts,
concluding that most contract violators would be subject to tort liability
since “the violation of most contracts involves a breach of faith.
48
In
other words, the court seemed to believe that because contract
violations are common, they should not be subject to tort liability and
potential punitive damages. But the court did not explain why bad
faith breaches do not justify tort liability and the imposition of punitive
damages.
In the absence of meaningful discussions of punitive damages,
judges have relied, in part, on economic theories to support the denial
of punitive damages in a holdup. As explained in part IIIA,
45
Id. at 54-55.
46
Sullivan, supra note 14, at 221.
47
457 F. Supp. 1158 (E.D. Pa. 1978).
48
Id. at 1165 n.7.
76 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
opportunistic behavior does not create wealth or enlarge the size of the
economic pie, but simply redistributes wealth from the nonbreaching
party to the breaching party.
49
Opportunistic breaches may go further
and actually reduce the size of the pie because “potential opportunists
and victims expend resources perpetrating and protecting against
opportunism.”
50
The opportunist may spend time and money looking
for loopholes in a contract and the victim may spend its own time and
money protecting itself from the opportunist’s behavior.
51
Thus, as Judge Posner recognizes, the law should discourage
opportunistic breaches of contract:
If a promisor breaks his promise merely to take advantage of the
vulnerability of the promisee in a setting (the normal contract setting)
where performance is sequential rather than simultaneous, we might
as well throw the book at the promisor. An example would be where
A pays B in advance for goods and instead of delivering them B uses
the money in another venture. Such conduct has no economic
justification and ought simply to be deterred.
52
As Judge Posner’s quote illustrates, no economic efficiency results
and the breaching party is rewarded for the holdup. If courts restrict
their awards to expectation damages in holdups, the stickup man will
ultimately learn that breaching contracts is a profitable venture.
Judge Posner stated the argument for damages beyond expectation
damages when a promisor breaches opportunistically, “we might as
well throw the book at the promisor. . . . Such conduct has no economic
justification and ought simply to be deterred.
53
Punitive damages
would provide the appropriate deterrence.
A “holdup” that could be characterized as an efficient breach finds
only flawed support in the theory of creating a Pareto improvement
through an efficient breach. Support for the encouragement of an
efficient breach seems to find its roots in Justice Holmes’ The Common
Law:
The only universal consequence of a legally binding promise is, that
the law makes the promisor pay damages if the promised event does
not come to pass. In every case it leaves him free from interference
49
George M. Cohen, The Negligence Opportunism Tradeoff in Contract Law, 20
H
OFSTRA L. REV. 941, 973 (1992).
50
Timothy J. Muris, Opportunistic Behavior and the Law of Contracts, 65 MINN. L.
REV. 521, 524 (1981).
51
Id.
52
RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 131 (5th ed. 1998).
53
Id. at 130.
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 77
until the time for fulfilment has gone by, and therefore free to break
his contract if he chooses.
54
Judge Posner, in favor of punitive damages for opportunistic
breaches does not find the same need for punitive damages with an
efficient breach:
Even if the breach is deliberate, it is not necessarily blameworthy.
The promisor may simply have discovered that his performance is
worth more to someone else. If so, efficiency is promoted by allowing
him to break his promise, provided he makes good the promisee’s
actual losses. If he is forced to pay more than that, an efficient breach
may be deterred, and the law doesn’t want to bring about such a
result.
55
Judge Posner has also commented that “Holmes’s dictum . . .
contains an important economic insight. In many cases it is
uneconomical to induce completion of performance of a contract.
56
Continuing on this point, “The modern theory of efficient breach is an
extension of Holmes’ outlook on contractual remedy.
57
In other words,
the rationale underlying the encouragement of efficient breach is that
expectation damages due to the promise will ensure the promisor will
breach only when the gains from breach exceed the legal damages.
Conversely, the promisor will be discouraged from breaching when
gains from the breach do not exceed the legal damages.
58
There are a number of problems with this analysis. The efficient
breach argument assumes that the breaching party willingly agrees to
compensate for the nonbreaching party’s actual losses and does not try
to take advantage of the costs of litigation to avoid paying damages or
settle for a lesser amount. The efficient breach argument also assumes
that expectation damages do, in fact, put the nonbreaching party in as
good a position as performance. However, this argument ignores the
fact that nonbreaching parties may not recover for emotional distress,
negative public speculation regarding the reason the breaching party
backed out, potential secondary business clients who are now leery of
contracting with the non-breaching party, attorneys’ fees, or
54
OLIVER WENDELL HOLMES, JR., THE COMMON LAW 301 (1881).
55
Patton v. Mid-Continent Sys., 841 F.2d 742, 750 (7th Cir. 1988).
56
POSNER, supra note 53.
57
Daniel Friedmann, The Efficient Breach Fallacy, The Journal of Legal Studies, Vol.
18, No. 1. (Jan. 1989), pp. 1-24, 2.
58
Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Liquidated Damages, Penalties and the Just
Compensation Principle: Some Notes on an Enforcement Model and a Theory of Efficient
Breach, 77 COLUM. L. REV. 554, 558 (1977).
78 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
prejudgment interest leaving the nonbreaching party in a hole dug by
someone else and as a result without adequate expectation damages.
59
The promisor often finds breach attractive not because anticipated
gains from the breach exceed anticipated losses, but because she never
intends to pay damages.
60
For example, one who contracts to sell goods
at a specified price has no incentive to breach a contract when market
price rises, since the gains derived by selling to an alternative
purchaser at the higher rate will be offset by the promisee’s legal
damages. But if the seller never intends to compensate the promisee
for her legal damages, there is nothing to discourage a breach. In a
system in which a breach, coupled with a refusal to pay resulting
damages, is often its own reward, it is not surprising that intentional
breach often occurs.
Ultimately, if the breaching party is not responsible for the
nonbreaching party’s full losses or has no intention of compensating
the nonbreaching party for losses, then there is an incentive to breach
even when the breach would not be efficient.
61
In addition, the doctrine
suffers from its own logic in that the breach allocates the benefit of the
breach to the breaching party. Klass illustrates the improper
distribution of gains under our current legal system using the following
fact pattern.
The original contract promised $4 per unit in net gains from
performance, $2 profit to Seller and $2 profit to Buyer. Third Party’s
offer to pay $13 for the goods created the opportunity for the parties
to realize between them a $5 per unit gain ($13 price - $8 Seller costs
= $5). If, as the efficient breach theory recommends, Seller breaches,
pays expectation damages, and sells the goods to Third Party, Seller
pockets the $1 difference ($3 profit vs. $2 profit) and buyer comes out
even ($2 expectation damages). If, on the contrary, Seller delivers the
goods, Buyer might sell them to Third Party. Now, as compared to the
first transaction, Seller comes out even ($2 profit), whereas Buyer
receives the extra $1 from the sale to Third Party ($13 resale price -
$10 contract price = $3). The theory of efficient breach is morally
problematic not only because it encourages a moral wrong, but also
59
See, e.g., C. Delos Putz, Jr. & Nona Klippen, Commercial Bad Faith: Attorney Fees—
Not Tort Liability—Is the Remedy for “Stonewalling”, 21 U.S.F. L. R
EV. 419, 452-60
(1987); (arguing that awarding attorneys’ fees is preferable to awarding punitive
damages).
60
Thomas A. Diamond, The Tort of Bad Faith Breach of Contract: When, If At All,
Should It Be Extended Beyond Insurance Transactions? 64 M
ARQ. L. REV. 425 (1981).
Available at: http://scholarship.law.marquette.edu/mulr/vol64/iss3/1 .
61
See, e.g., John A. Sebert, Jr., Punitive and Nonpecuniary Damages in Actions Based
upon Contract: Toward Achieving the Objective of Full Compensation, 33 U.C.L.A. L.
REV. 1565, 1573. (1986). (“By systematically undercompensating plaintiffs, we risk
encouraging too much breach rather than too little.”).
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 79
because it would allocate all the gains from that wrong to the
wrongdoer.
62
Dual performance hypothesis attempts to support our current legal
system and the concept of an efficient breach. In short, the hypothesis
postulates that no breach has occurred if the breaching party pays
expectation damages because those damages fulfill the obligation to
the nonbreaching party. To reach this result, the dual performance
hypothesis holds that the typical promisor makes a promise to deliver
goods or services in return for consideration or to pay damages when
the promisee chooses not to deliver or perform. Therefore, the promisor
“breaches” only when she fails to deliver and refuses to pay.
63
This
theory assumes that the promisee receives “the equivalent of the
promised performance” when the promisor merely pays expectation
damages. This transfer is “the exact scope of what was promised in the
event” that the promisor does not tender.
64
The logic of the dual performance hypothesis requires us to assume
that parties enter into contracts with this theory in mind. In other
words, the parties interpret their contract as including a promise to
either perform or pay expectation damages.
65
Supporters would argue
that the pricing of the contract relies on this assumption. In other
words, the promisor charges less for the goods or services assuming
that a breach would require only the payment of expectation
damages.
66
Therefore, permitting punitive damages, specific
performance, disgorgement or other remedies would require a
corresponding increase in the price. Because of the price advantage
received by the promisee, the promisee will often be the beneficiary of
contract gains resulting from the logic of the dual performance
hypothesis.
A normative analysis of dual performance has found few supporters.
Frederick Pollock, critical of this logic, wrote the following in 1891:
A man who bespeaks a coat of his tailor will scarcely be persuaded
that he is only betting with the tailor that such a coat will not be made
62
Gregory Klass, Efficient Breach, in the Philosophical Foundations of Contract Law
(G. Klass, G. Letsas & P. Saprai, eds., Oxford University Press, forthcoming).
http://scholarship.law.georgetown.edu/facpub/1185/.
63
Note that dual performance assumes an efficient breach and does not address
inefficient breaches.
64
Alan Schwartz and Daniel Markovits, The Myth of Efficient Breach (2010). Faculty
Scholarship Series. Paper 93. http://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/fss_papers/93 .
65
Id.
66
Id.
80 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
and delivered to him within a certain time. What he wants and means
to have is the coat, not an insurance against not having the coat.
67
More recently, Stephen Smith wrote “[i]t just seems implausible, as
a matter of fact, to regard contracting parties as having agreed, in the
typical case, to disjunctive obligations to perform or compensate.
68
Others have more generally dismissed the theory. Andrew Gold wrote
that “as a general description of what parties intend, or even as an
interpretation of the public meaning of contract language, [the dual
performance hypothesis] seems inadequate.”
69
Indeed, the Uniform
Commercial Code notes that “the essential purpose of a contract
between commercial [parties] is actual performance and they do not
bargain merely for a promise, or for a promise plus the right to win a
lawsuit.”
70
The dual performance hypothesis fails to adequately
support limiting damages for an efficient breach. Rather, it seems to
constitute a contrived attempt to support existing law by proposing a
change to the interpretation of the bargain by the parties to the
contract.
The social argument for encouraging efficient breaches of contract
begins with a recognition that if breaches are too harshly sanctioned,
there will be deterrence not only of breach but of the execution of
contracts.
71
“[I]f damages are awarded to secure expectation interest in
order to encourage the making of contract promises, to introduce
damage measuring law which goes beyond the value of expectations
may introduce a deterrent to the very contract making behavior to be
encouraged.” Therefore, damages must not be so oppressive as to
discourage the formation of binding commercial agreements.”
72
Our current legal system in which a breach, often coupled with a
refusal to pay resulting damages, seems to encourage willful breaches
or holdups. Without an effective deterrent to holdups, the system
encourages service hold outs, and bad faith refusals to pay. When
balanced against these defects, damages going beyond expectation
damages are warranted and far outweigh the need to encourage the
execution of contracts.
67
FREDERICK POLLOCK, PRINCIPLES OF CONTRACT XIX (London, Stevens &
Sons rev. 3d ed. 1881).
68
STEPHEN A. SMITH, CONTRACT THEORY 402 (2004).
69
Andrew S. Gold, A Property Theory of Contract, 103 NORTHWESTERN UNIV. L. REV.
1, 54 (2009).
70
8UCC § 2-609 cmt. 1 (2003).
71
Hartzler, The Business and Economic Functions of the Law of Contract Damages, 6
A
MER. BUS. L.J. 387, 392 (1968).
72
Gardner, An Inquiry Into the Principles of the Law of Contracts, 46 HARV. L. REV.
1, 29 (1932).
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 81
III. CAN EXISTING ECONOMIC THEORY WITHSTAND ETHICAL
SCRUTINY
As explained in Part II, there is little to no support to be found in
either legal or economic theories for opportunistic breaches of contract.
Efficient breaches, however, have found some support in economic
theories. This Part III explores willful breaches, and more specifically,
efficient breaches, from an ethical perspective.
A. Introduction to Ethical Behavior
The theory of “efficient breach” has by its very name curb appeal.
Its name states categorically that it is efficient, a presumably good
outcome.
73
It is an economic theory and given the contractual backdrop
of the discussion, has certain legitimacy. After all economics is: “a
social science concerned chiefly with description and analysis of the
production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services.”
74
These are areas in which contracts abound: Article 2 of the Uniform
Commercial Code deals with the sale of goods
75
and common law
contracts deals with the sale of services. Therefore isn’t economics the
proper point of our analysis? What could be better than efficiency?
Yet the definitions of efficiency seem to vary depending on the
discipline. In economics it means: “an economic state in which every
resource is optimally allocated to serve each individual or entity in the
best way while minimizing waste and inefficiency.”
76
In investments,
efficiency means: “a level of performance that describes a process that
uses the lowest amount of inputs to create the greatest amount of
outputs.”
77
If we view contracts as an integral part of our society one
need ask what we are attempting to achieve through the use of
contracts in our society. Are we attempting to create the greatest
amount of outputs? Are we attempting to minimize waste? Or are we
attempting to increase social welfare?
So, if we presume that the purpose of contracts is to improve society,
then it follows that we should mold our contract law to maximize this
benefit or good to society. But what do we mean by something which
is good for society or a benefit to society? To evaluate the overall value
73
2017 Daniel Seth Lewis, Is Efficiency a Good Thing, (March 23, 2017)
http://www.danielsethlewis.com/2013/09/is-efficiency-good-thing.html.
74
Merriam-Webster, Definition of Economics, (March 23, 2017) https://www.merriam-
webster.com/dictionary/economics.
75
Article 2 of the UCC: Definition & Terms, Study.com (March 23, 2017)
http://study.com/academy/lesson/article-2-of-the-ucc-definition-terms.html.
76
Economic Efficiency, Investopedia, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/e/economic_
efficiency.asp, (March 23, 2017).
77
Id.
82 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
to society of efficient breach as a concept we must first understand the
notion of what it means to act in a good or beneficial way. To do this
we need to look at the ethics of our society. Ethics can be thought of
as, “a set of moral principles, or an area of study that deals with ideas
about what is good and bad behavior.
78
Morality (as differentiated
from morals) can be looked at as “conformity to ideals of right human
conduct.”
79
In everyday life most people would agree that acting
ethically is a benefit to society. In the business setting many people
also espouse acting ethically for various reasons. Amy Rees Anderson,
founder and managing partner of ReesCapital and prior CEO of
MediConnect Global, Inc., offers the following advice on achieving
success: “Do the right thing and let the consequences follow.”
80
Others
believe that, “a business must keep in tune with the wishes of the
societies it serves or it runs the risk of alienating its shareholders,
stakeholders and customers. This would be bad for business, reducing
growth and potentially affecting profit.”
81
Ms. Anderson’s comments
tend more towards the inspirational while the latter comment tends
more towards a nod to ethical conduct being necessary to garner more
profits.
Regardless of which of these justifications for ethical behavior is
correct, the question still remains what is the right thing to do? Is the
right thing or the ethical thing or the good thing always the same in
all circumstances? Is the proper behavior the same regardless of
position, station, and circumstance? Am I always my brother’s keeper?
B. Common Ethical Theories Outlining Good Behavior
Philosophers have grappled with the concepts of good and evil, right
and wrong, for centuries. Despite the vastness of ethical theories on
the subject, a review of some of the more prevalent ones will be helpful
in answering some of the questions posed. As a very general premise,
most ethical theories can be divided into either duty based systems
(deontology) or consequence based systems (teleology).
82
A duty based
system chooses conduct based on what ought to be done regardless of
78
MERRIAM-WEBSTERS COLLEGIATE DICTIONARY, Eleventh Edition, available at
http://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/.
79
Id.
80
Amy Rees Anderson, Do the Right Thing, Amy Rees Anderson Blog (March, 23,
2017), http://www.amyreesanderson.com/blog/do-the-right-thing/.
81
Business Ethics and Corporate Social Responsibility, and Anglo American Case
Study (March 23, 2017) http://businesscasestudies.co.uk/anglo-american/business-
ethics-and-corporate-social-responsibility/why-should-a-business-act-ethically.html.
82
GERALD R. FERRARA, MYSTICA M. ALEXANDER, WILLIAM P. WIGGINS, CHERYL
KIRSCHNER AND JONATHAN DARROW, THE LEGAL AND ETHICAL ENVIRONMENT OF
BUSINESS, (2014) p. 47.
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 83
the consequences of that conduct whereas a consequence based system
demands conduct based on the outcome of the conduct.
83
Some ethical
theories contain elements of both duty based systems and consequence
based systems.
84
Saint Thomas Aquinas can be viewed as one of those
philosophers whose theory may delve into both camps.
85
St. Thomas Aquinas viewed law or rules designed to circumscribe
our conduct as “a rule or measure of human acts, whereby a person is
induced to act or is restrained from acting
86
It is a boundary for our
conduct which was related to and rooted in reason.
87
Where might this
reason begin? Aquinas would say in being or in the beginning of life.
88
Aquinas felt that all reason was directed towards achieving good.
“Good is to be done and evil is to be avoided.”
89
For Aquinas this “good
or natural state is one which originates from the eternal law and is
endowed within us from the very beginning of life, giving us an innate
internal sense of good.
90
Yet if we have this internal sense of the good
why do we as a people deviate from that direction. For Aquinas the
answer is clear: our skewed behavior has its roots in original sin.
91
Despite the significant influence of original sin on human behavior, St
Thomas Aquinas does believe that our actions are driven for the most
part by the influence of God.
92
His approach highlights the conflict of
desires which individuals sometimes feel within. For Aquinas, the
actions of the opportunist
93
are incongruous with the nature of the
good: “Whoever walks in integrity walks securely, but whoever takes
crooked paths will be found out.”
94
Another approach which attempts to clarify right and wrong which
has endured the test of time is Utilitarianism. Utilitarianism is an
outcome based system.
95
Originated by Jeremy Bentham and further
refined by John Stuart Mill, Utilitarianism according to Jeremy
83
Religious Studies Online, Natural Law Theory (March 23, 2017)
http://www.rsrevision.com/Alevel/ethics/natural_law/.
84
Id.
85
Id.
86
ST Ia IIae 90.1, cited in Thomas Aquinas: Moral Philosophy, INTERNET
ENCYCLOPEDIA OF PHILOSOPHY (March 23, 2017) http://www.iep.utm.edu/aq-moral/#H4.
87
Thomas Aquinas: Moral Philosophy, INTERNET ENCYCLOPEDIA OF PHILOSOPHY,
http://www.iep.utm.edu/aq-moral/#H4, (March 23, 2017).
88
William S. Brewbaker III, Thomas Aquinas and the Metaphysics of Law, 58
ALABAMA L. REV. 575, 585 (2007).
89
Id. at 602.
90
Id. at 595.
91
Id. at 610.
92
Id. at 586.
93
The opportunist here is equivalent to our stickup man in the holdup.
94
Proverbs 10 NIV.
95
FERRARA, et. al., supra note 88, at 52.
84 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
Bentham looked at whether the act produces pleasure or happiness
and prevented pain and suffering.
96
John Stuart Mill in refining
Bentham’s ideas stated: “actions are right in proportion as they tend
to promote happiness; wrong as they tend to produce the reverse of
happiness. By happiness is intended pleasure and the absence of pain;
by unhappiness, pain and the privation of pleasure.
97
Additionally,
Mills believed that our actions should strive to be those which benefited
society as a whole in addition to benefiting ourselves.
98
Mill’s felt that
it was in our nature to be nurturing to society as a whole, and that by
seeking happiness for our fellow man we too would thus be benefited.
99
One can see how Mills links positive outcomes for society with positive
actions for self. Also, the instinctive nature of man’s desire to act in
furtherance of society seems to resonate with concepts espoused by St
Thomas Aquinas above of having some pre-ordained notion of acting
towards the good of society.
Yet when we are looking towards choosing our actions in a way
which maximizes the good or the beneficial outcome to society, how far
does that obligation extend? The answer to this depends on how one
defines society. Webster defines it as: “the people of a particular
country, area, time, etc., thought of especially as an organized
community.”
100
So if we pick our community as society, what if our
actions are viewed by some in our society as producing happiness while
others do not? The difficulty faced by Bentham and Mills’ theory is
that it presupposes an understanding of what is beneficial and good.
This lack of clarity can make its application in practice very difficult.
Thus in an effort to add clarity to these theories some proponents of
Utilitarianism looked to Christian religious ideals as a way of
harmonizing the interests of the individual, who are motivated by their
own happiness with the interests of society as a whole.
101
Consider the
holdup of the star athlete in the light of Utilitarianism. One wonders
if the Star Player thinks that he is acting with integrity when he holds
his team up for more money by breaking his word to play. Utilitarians
would look at his actions and say the greatest good can be achieved
only by following the moral path, rather than worldly desires (such as
economic efficiency).
96
Id.
97
John Stuart Mill (1806-1873), INTERNET ENCYCLOPEDIA OF PHILOSOPHY (MARCH 23,
2017) http://www.iep.utm.edu/milljs/#SH2d.
98
Id.
99
Id.
100
Merriam-Webster, (March 23, 2017) https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/society.
101
John Stuart Mill (1806-1873), INTERNET ENCYCLOPEDIA OF PHILOSOPHY (March 23,
2017) http://www.iep.utm.edu/milljs/#SH2d.
2017 / Stick ‘Em Up This is a Breach / 85
The final theory we will examine is that stated by Emmanuel Kant
in his categorical imperative. “Act only on that maxim whereby thou
canst at the same time will that it [your action] should become a
universal law.”
102
The categorical imperative can be stated simply by
using the following approach. Take whatever action you are
contemplating and then universalize it. Or to put it differently, would
you consider your action to have a good result if everyone were to follow
the same conduct. The method advanced by Kant is a duty based
system where doing the correct thing is the best choice regardless of
the outcome. So for Kant we should consider doing the right thing
regardless of its consequences.
103
The right course of conduct being
determined by having everyone act in the same way and presumably
multiplying any negative effect of the conduct. Thus if after
universalizing the action it is still viewed as good then it must be so.
Looking at Kantian philosophy, there is a sort of symmetry between
parts of his philosophy and the proverb, “do unto others as you would
have them do unto you.”
104
For Kant acting in a moral way was paramount regardless of the
outcome. For example, Kant felt that, lying is something which is to
be avoided, “as it was contrary to our moral dignity.”
105
Both the
opportunist and the efficient breacher are telling a lie if they entered
the contract knowing that they would consider breaching the contract
in the event something better comes along.
While no one philosophical method has the perfect solution to what
is a good or beneficial result, each put acting in a way which is good
ahead of acting in a self-centered way. There seem to be no ethical
theorists who espouse a theory of good centering itself on economic
efficiency or on economics at all. Some theories attempt to make
morality a simple matter by reducing good conduct to imperatives
without considering consequences. Others give us vague generalities
to maximize the good without telling us what specifically is the good.
And others tell us to do that which is innately within us. Nonetheless,
all theories seem to search for something more. They center the good
or acting in a good way around an idea which is beyond that for which
men, who lack integrity, strive. They all see one’s word as a priceless
thing, rather than something which can be dismissed and compensated
with the latest coin of the realm. When a man makes a vow…or takes
an oath to obligate himself by a pledge, he must not break his word but
102
FERRARA, supra note 88, at 50.
103
Id.
104
Luke 6:31(New International Version).
105
Tim C. Mazur, Lying, ISSUES IN ETHICS, (v.6, n.1, Fall 1993),
https://www.scu.edu/ethics/publications/iie/v6n1/lying.html.
86 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
must do everything he said.”
106
Let us be a society of people whose laws
help us along the straight and narrow moral path rather than one
which dispenses morality for economic efficiency.
IV. CONCLUSION
It seems the faster we move, and the more sophisticated we believe
our society to be, the more we lose track of our origins. We want to
prove we know best and that morality, contracts, and law need to be
kept distinct. Yet there was a time in our history when a sense of
fairness was part of the law.
107
What happened to the time when we
listened to our conscience, and economics and morality did not sleep in
the same bed? As the Blue Fairy in Pinocchio said, “a conscience ought
to be Lord High Keeper of the knowledge of right and wrong, counselor
in moments of temptation, and a guide along the straight and narrow
path.”
108
The straight and narrow has no room for the holdup artist,
the Star Athlete who can sink a basket at will but who has no integrity,
or the supplier who can be economically efficient but who has no
morality.
Rather than deter holdups, our current legal system actually
encourages such breaches. These holdups serve no societal function,
find no support in economic theory, and violate the sanctity of our
promises and our moral concepts of justice. Damages going beyond
expectation damages are warranted. Punitive damages seem to be a
fitting consequence of a holdup in that they were designed with exactly
such a deterrent effect in mind. In the words of Posner, “[i]f a promisor
breaks his promise merely to take advantage of the vulnerability of the
promisee . . . we might as well throw the book at [him].”
109
Let punitive
damages be that book.
106
Numbers 30:2 NIV.
107
Morton J. Horwitz, supra note 15, at 925 (citing Pledger v. Wade, 1 Bay 35, 37 (S.C.
1786)).
108
https://ohmy.disney.com/movies/2013/04/05/we-wish-jiminy-cricket-was-our-conscience/.
109
POSNER, supra note 48, at 105.
THE DEVELOPING LAW OF EMPLOYEE NON-
COMPETITION AGREEMENTS: CORRECTING
ABUSES; MAKING ADJUSTMENTS TO ENHANCE
ECONOMIC GROWTH
by David P. Twomey
I. INTRODUCTION:
Non-compete employment contracts prohibit employees from
working for a competing employer for a set period of time after leaving
their employment.
1
Today, non-compete agreements not only affect
chief executive officers, managers, engineers, scientists and
information technology specialists,
2
but also lower wage earners such
as fast food employees and hair stylists.
3
The U.S. Department of the
Treasury recently issued a report raising concerns about the misuse of
non-competes across education, occupation and income groups and the
resulting adverse implications for worker bargaining power, job
1
Note. This paper deals with non-compete employment contracts. Restrictions in a
contract of sale of a business prohibiting the seller from going into the same or similar
business again within a certain geographic area, for a certain period of time are enforced
in all states. Even California, which prohibits all employee non-compete agreements in
section 16600 of its Business Professional Code has statutory exceptions that cover and
protect sales of a business whether effected through the sale of the business’s assets, the
sale of shares in a corporation, or the sale of a partnership interest. See Cal. Bus. & Prof.
Code § 16601 (2016) (sale of goodwill or corporation shares; agreement not to compete);
id. §16602 (partners; dissolution, dissociation, or sale; agreement not to compete).
2
See EMC Corporation v. Clesle, 2016 Mass. Super. LEXIS 124 (May 13, 2016).
3
See Hair Club for Men, LLC v. Ehson, 2016 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 118069 (E.D. Va. May
6, 2016).
88 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
mobility and economic growth.
4
Developing law through court
decisions and state legislative activity continues to weigh, balance and
adjust protections for legitimate employer interests while not unduly
burdening employees and the economic growth of regional economies.
II. LEGAL TRENDS IN SELECTED STATES
The Restatement (Second) of Contracts sets forth the general
principles for states to enforce non-compete agreements considering:
(1) whether “the restraint is greater than needed to protect the
[employer’s] legitimate interests; (2) the hardship to the [employee];
and (3) the likely injury to the public.
5
The employer’s legitimate
business interests may include confidential information, trade secrets
and customer good will.
6
Overly broad geographic and time restrictions
are unenforceable.
7
While the majority of states reflect the
Restatement’s principles, they do so guided by the rule of reason,
resulting however in somewhat different, evolving formulations in
different states.
A. Massachusetts Case Law: Blue Penciling Overbroad Restrictions:
Banning Restrictions on Ordinary Competition for Conventionally
Skilled Service Providers
When an employer discovers that a former employee is working for
a competitor in violation of a non-compete agreement, through counsel
it may notify the new employer and threaten litigation;
8
and, if not
successful, the former employee may seek a preliminary injunction in
state or federal court prohibiting the violation of the non-compete
agreement.
9
Motions for preliminary injunctions are heard
expeditiously by the courts and are ordinarily used to preserve the
status quo pending trial on the merits. However, in non-compete cases
the validity of the time limitation in the non-compete agreement is
4
Office of Economic Policy, U.S. Department of the Treasury, “Non-Compete
Contracts: Economic Effects and Policy Implications” www.treasury.gov, p.6 (March
2016).
5
Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 188 (1981).
6
DAVID TWOMEY, MARIANNE JENNINGS & STEPHANIE GREENE, BUSINESS LAW,
PRINCIPLES FOR TODAYS COMMERCIAL ENVIRONMENT. pp. 277, 278 (5th ed. 2017).
7
Id.
8
In Socko v. Mid-Atlantic Systems of CPA, Inc. 126 A. 3d 1266 (Pa. 2015) the
employer notified the new employer and threatened litigation resulting in Socko’s
termination. Socko successfully challenged this action, with the court deciding that the
agreement was unenforceable for lack of consideration because it was entered into after
the commencement of Socko’s employment with his former employer, Mid-Atlantic.
9
See EMC Corporation v. Clesle, 2016 Mass. Super. LEXIS 124 at *7 (May 13, 2016).
2017 / Developing Law of Employee Non-Competition Agreements / 89
clothed with immediacy. Decisions at the preliminary injunction stage
become, in effect, a determination on the merits.
10
In order to obtain a preliminary injunction a plaintiff must show: (1)
a likelihood of success on the merits; (2) that irreparable harm will
result from denial of the injunction; and (3) that, in light of the
plaintiff’s likelihood of success on the merits, the risk of irreparable
harm to the plaintiff outweighs the potential harm to the defendant in
granting the injunction.
11
Regarding Massachusetts technology
industries, state and federal courts enforce non-compete and non-
disclosure agreements to protect against inevitable or even inadvertent
disclosure.
12
In SimpliVity Corp. v. Moran, the court allowed a
preliminary injunction against Keith Moran, enjoining him from
working for a competing start up, Nutanix, or any other firm in the
data storage industry for a year even though he promised not to solicit
the customers of his former employer, SimpliVity.
13
The court
determined that he would inevitably use the SimpliVity confidential
information in his brain memory in selling Nutanix’s products and
competing against SimpliVity.
14
In Massachusetts, rather than declining entirely to give effect to an
unreasonable non-competitive clause, a court may modify its terms so
as to make it reasonable.
15
Partial enforcement is sometimes called
“blue penciling” – a throwback to the days when lawyers edited written
work with a blue pencil.
16
In Perficient, Inc. v. Priore, the court found
that the two year restriction in the non-compete clause was longer than
reasonably necessary to protect the employer, Perficient, from a 23
year old college graduate who had only worked for the client at issue
for nine months.
17
The court revised the restrictions to a one year
period.
18
Enforcement of non-competition clauses in Massachusetts is limited
to the extent they serve a legitimate business interest of the employer
such as protection of trade secrets, confidential business information
10
Horner International Co. v. McCoy, 754 S.E. 2d 852 (2014).
11
SimpliVity Corp. v. Moran, 2016 Mass Super. LEXIS 297 at *21 (Aug. 14, 2016).
12
Id. See also SimpliVity Corp. v. Bondranko, 2016 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 117448 at *10
(D. Mass. Aug. 31, 2016).
13
Moran, 2016 Mass. Super. LEXIS 297 at *33.
14
Id.
15
Kroeger v. Stop & Shop Companies Inc., 13 Mass. App. Ct. 310, 312 (1982).
16
See Turnell v. Centimark Corp., 796 F.3d 656, 662 (7
th
Cir. 2015) for a discussion of
the origin of the term “blue penciling.”
17
Perficient, Inc. v. Priore, 2016 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 56704, at *20 (D. Mass April 26,
2016).
18
Id. at *19.
90 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
and customer good will.
19
An employer is not entitled to a preliminary
injunction to enforce a non-compete agreement against former
employees who possess no more than the conventional job knowledge
and skill readily obtainable from publicly available sources.
20
In
Elizabeth Grady Face First, Inc. v. Garabedian, the employer was not
entitled to a preliminary injunction on a non-compete agreement
against two former employees who operated a day spa nine miles from
the plaintiff’s shop.
21
The court found that there was no evidence that
the defendants were possessed of or exploiting bona fide trade secrets,
confidential information, or customer good will belonging to the
Company, rather the court stated it was evident that Elizabeth Grady’s
true motivation was to thwart ordinary competition from
conventionally skilled service providers. The court determined that
this was not permissible under Massachusetts law.
22
B. Virginia Case Law: No Reforming Overbroad Non-Compete
Agreements
Covenants that restrain trade are disfavored by Virginia courts.
23
The employer must show that the restraint in a non-compete clause is
necessary to protect a legitimate business interest, is not unduly harsh
in curtailing an employer’s ability to earn a livelihood and is reasonable
in light of sound public policy.
24
The courts analyze the restrictions in
terms of function, geographic scope and duration.
25
Unlike Massachusetts courts, Virginia courts have no authority to
“blue pencil” or otherwise reform or rewrite overly broad restrictions in
a non-compete contract.
26
In Home Paramount Pest Control v. Shaffer
the non-compete provision prohibited Shaffer from “engag[ing]
indirectly or concern[ing] himself… in any manner whatsoever” in pest
control “as an owner, agent, servant, representative, or employee
and/or as a member of a partnership and/or as an officer, director or
stockholder of any corporation, or in any manner whatsoever.”…
27
Because the non-compete provision did not confine the “function’
element to those activities Shaffer actually engaged in for the
19
See Elizabeth Grady Face First, Inc. v. Garabedian et al, 2016 Mass. Super. LEXIS
34 at *5 (Mar. 25, 2016).
20
See id. at *7.
21
See id. at *13.
22
Id. at *11.
23
Hair Club for Men, LLC v. Ehson, 2016 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 118069 at *7 (E.D. Va.
Aug. 31, 2016). See also Modern Environments, Inc. v. Stinnett, 263 Va 491 (2002).
24
Id.
25
Simmons v. Miller, 261 Va. 561,581 (2001).
26
Landmark Tech, Inc. v. Canales, 454 F. Supp. 2d 529 (E.D. Va. 2006).
27
Home Paramount Pest Control v. Shaffer, 282 Va. 412, 416 (2011).
2017 / Developing Law of Employee Non-Competition Agreements / 91
employer, the court found the non-compete provision was overbroad
and unenforceable.
28
In NVR Inc. v. Nelson the court determined that the geographic
scope of the non-compete provision was indefinite and could possibly
extend to at least fourteen states.
29
Accordingly, the court found the
geographic scope of the non-compete provision overbroad and thus not
valid.
30
C. Washington State Case Law Protecting Low Wage Workers
Like most other states, Washington law disfavors restraints on
trade regarding covenants not to compete and other restrictive
covenants such as non-solicitation clauses.
31
This is especially true
when low wage, at-will employees are involved. In Genex Cooperative,
Inc. v. Contreras, the court refused to enforce a non-compete clause
against a low-level agricultural worker with an employment-at-will
relationship with the employer.
32
It determined that the restrictive
covenant was unreasonable because the at-will employee may be
terminated without any cause and then be prohibited from seeking new
employment in his line of work.
33
Regarding another former Genex
bovine inseminator, the court stated that it appeared to the court that
the employer actually used restrictive covenants to eliminate
competition or to strong-arm employees to accept ever-dwindling
wages and restrict their freedom to work.
34
The court determined that
the non-competition agreement was unenforceable as a matter of law
and would not be reformed.
35
D. Illinois Law: Protecting Low Wage Workers
Illinois follows the general rule that covenants not to compete are
valid if they are reasonable in purpose and scope and are supported by
adequate consideration.
36
In 2016 the state took action against a fast
28
Id. at 418.
29
NVR Inc. v. Nelson, 2017 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 21829 at *21 (Feb. 14, 2017).
30
Id.
31
See Knight, Vale & Gregory v. McDaniel, 37 Wash. App. 366, 370 (1984).
32
Genex Cooperative, Inc. v. Conteras, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 141417 at *21 (E.D.
Wash. Oct. 3, 2014).
33
Id at *18.
34
Id.
35
Id.
36
For a discussion of Illinois law on adequate consideration see McInnis v. OAG
Motorcycle Ventures, LLC, 35 N.E.3d 1076, 1083 (Ill. App. 2015) (employment alone of
an at-will employee is not considered adequate consideration to support enforcement of
a non-compete clause; an employer’s promise of continued employment may be an
illusory benefit where the employment is at-will; the court determined that continued
employment for super motorcycle salesman Chris McInnis of eighteen months was
92 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
food franchise for requiring low wage workers to sign non-compete
agreements. Illinois Attorney General Lisa Madigan filed a lawsuit on
June 8, 2016 against Jimmy John’s Sandwich Shops seeking injunctive
and other equitable relief contending:
… that Jimmy John’s use of non-compete agreements for at-will, low
wage workers limits the ability of employees to find new employment,
… hinders upward mobility of workers looking for higher wages or
advancement with new employment using skills obtained in their
current employment, and suppresses wages for employees who have
limited negotiating power with both current and potential new
employers when they are limited by a non-competition agreement.
37
All store employees are employees at-will, and all store employees in
Illinois were required to sign a non-competition covenant,
38
which
stated in part:
Non-Competition Covenant. Employee covenants and agrees that,
during his or her employment with Employer and for a period of two
(2) years after… he or she will not have any direct or indirect interest
in or perform services for (whether as an owner, partner, investor,
director, officer, representative, manager, employee, principal, agent,
advisor, or consultant) any business which derives more than ten
percent (10%) of its revenue from selling submarine, hero type, deli-
style, pita and/or wrapped or rolled sandwiches and which is located
within three (3) miles of either (1) ________ [Insert address of
employment], or (2) any such other JIMMY JOHN’S Sandwich Shop
operated by JJF, one of its authorized franchisees, or any of JJF’s
affiliates....
Costs and Attorney’s Fees. Employee agrees to reimburse
Employer and JJF for all costs and expenses, including attorney’s fees,
that Employer or JJF incur to enforce this Agreement against
Employee.
39
On December 7, 2016 the parties announced a settlement with
Jimmy John’s, in which the company, among other things, is required
to notify all current and former employees that their non-compete
agreements are unenforceable and that Jimmy John’s does not intend
to enforce them.
40
insufficient consideration).
37
Complaint, Illinois v. Jimmy John’s Enterprise, LLC., 2016 CCH 07746 at 17.
38
Id. at 5.
39
Id. at Exhibit A.
40
Illinois Attorney General Madigan Announces Settlement With Jimmy John’s For
Imposing Unlawful Non-Compete Agreements,” http://www.illinoisattorneygeneral.gov/
pressroom/2016_ 12/20161207.
2017 / Developing Law of Employee Non-Competition Agreements / 93
Effective January 1, 2017 the Illinois Freedom to Work Act bans the
use of non-compete agreements for those earning less than $13.50 per
hour.
41
E. California: Continuing Its Ban on Non-Competes
California does not follow the general rule that covenants not to
compete are valid if they are reasonable in purpose and scope.
California Business and Professions Code section 16600 states, “Except
as provided in this chapter, every contract by which anyone is
restrained from engaging in a lawful profession, trade or business of
any kind is to that extent void.
42
The policy behind California’s rule as
expressed by the California Supreme Court states:
Every individual possesses as a form of property the right to pursue
any calling, business or profession he may choose. A former employee
has the right to engage in a competitive business for himself and to
enter into competition with his former employer provided such
competition is fairly and legally conducted.
43
However, agreements not to disclose an employer’s trade secrets
during or after the term of employment are fully enforceable.
44
Even though non-compete agreements are not enforced in
California, still California employers often require that workers sign
non-compete agreements there, with some 19 percent of workers
currently working under unenforceable non-compete agreements.
45
Applying to contracts entered into after January 1, 2017, California
law now prohibits the litigation outside of California of most
employment-related issues including non-compete and trade secret
matters affecting California based employees.
46
41
Illinois Freedom to Work Act, Public Act 099- 0860, Effective, January 1, 2017.
42
CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §16600 (2017).
43
Cont’l Car-Na-Var Corp. v. Mosely, 24 Cal.2d 104, 110 (Cal. 1944).
44
See, e.g. Muggill v. Reuben H. Donnelly Corp. 62 Cal.2d 239 (Cal. 1965).
45
Office of Economic Policy, U.S. Department of the Treasury “Non-compete Contracts
Economic Effects and Policy Implementations” (March 2016) p. 12.
46
CAL. LAB. CODE § 925 (2016) states:
(a) An employer shall not require an employee who primarily resides and works in
California, as a condition of employment, to agree to a provision that would do
either of the following:
(1) Require the employee to adjudicate outside of California a claim arising in
California.
(2) Deprive the employee of the substantive protection of California law with
respect to a controversy arising in California.
94 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
III. ADJUSTING NON-COMPETE LAW TO ATTRACT NEW HIGH
TECH VENTURES: MASSACHUSETTS AND CALIFORNIA
APPROACHES
Derived from the U.S. Department of the Treasury’s recent report
on “Non-Compete Contracts: Economic Effects and Policy
Implications,”
47
a recent White House paper summarized the position
that non-compete agreements can affect the mobility of workers,
clearly affecting a region’s growth as follows:
When firms in a given industry are clustered, it makes it easier for
their workers to share expertise and discoveries, some of which may
not be protected by trade secret or intellectual property legal
provisions. Economists refer to geographic clustering effects of factors
like a large, deep pool of skilled workers, a more competitive market
of suppliers, and information spillovers across workers and firms as
“agglomeration effects.”
While not necessarily in the interest of an individual firm, more rapid
dissemination of ideas and technology improvements can have
significant positive impacts for the larger regional economy in terms
of innovation, entrepreneurship, and attracting more businesses and
jobs to a region. Non-competes that stifle mobility of workers who can
disseminate knowledge and ideas to new startups or companies
moving to a region can limit the process that leads to agglomeration
economies. Overly broad non-compete provisions could prevent
potential entrepreneurs from starting new businesses in similar
sectors to their current employer, even if they relocate.
48
The research history for the positions set forth in the White House
paper on information spillovers across workers and firms as
“agglomeration effects” goes back to Professor Ronald Gilson’s 1999
article comparing the growth of California’s Silicon Valley and the
Route 128 corridor outside of Boston.
49
The post-employment non-
compete agreements applicable to Massachusetts employees presented
a barrier to the second-stage agglomeration economy that sustains a
high technology district by allowing it to reset its product life cycle, an
economy that did not develop on Route 128 but did in Silicon Valley.
50
With the idea of becoming more competitive with California in terms
of venture capital investments in new high tech enterprises and to
continue to invigorate its start-up community, Massachusetts
legislators recently set out to enact comprehensive legislation relating
47
Supra note 45, p. 22.
48
Non-compete Agreements: Analysis of the Usage, Political Issues and State
Responses” The White House, May 5, 2016. p. 22.
49
Ronald J. Gilson, “The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial Districts:
Silicon Valley, Route 128, and Covenants Not to Compete”, 74 N.Y.U.L. REV. 575 (1999).
50
Id. at 607.
2017 / Developing Law of Employee Non-Competition Agreements / 95
to non-compete agreements. In the summer of 2016 it proposed passage
of the Massachusetts Non Competition Agreement Act,
51
containing the
following major revisions:
y
y
The non competition agreement must be provided to the employee
by the earliest of a final offer of employment or 10 business day before
starting work.
52

y If signed after employment it must be supported by fair and
reasonable consideration in addition to continued employment.
53
y It must be tailored to protect legitimate business interests such as,
trade secrets, confidential business information and good will.
54
y It must not exceed one year in duration.
55
yIt must be reasonable in geographic territory, limited to areas where
the employee provided services in the last 2 years of employment.
56
y It must be reasonable in scope of prescribed activities, relating to
work activities the affected employee has performed over the last 2
years of employment.
57
y It may be judicially reformed.
58
y It will not apply to employees who have been terminated without
cause or laid off, or to student interns.
59
The proposed legislation contained a “garden leave” provision which
would require an employer to pay a worker a half year’s salary if the
worker could not take a new job due to the one year non-compete
provision.
60
Interest groups and legislators ran out of time with the ending of
the legislation session on July 31, 2016 without the necessary
51
H.B. 4434, § 24 L. (June 27, 2016) https://masslegislature.gov/bills/189/H.B.4434.html.
52
§ 24L (b)(i).
53
§ 24L (b)(ii).
54
§ 24L (b)(iii).
55
§ 24L(b)(iv).
56
§ 24L(b)(v).
57
§ 24L(b)(vi).
58
§ 24L(d). A May 19, 2016 version of the proposed legislation, H.B.4323, had stated
in subsection (d) that a non-compete agreement may not be judicially reformed.
59
§24L(c).
60
§ 24L(b)(vii). The subsection also contained the option of “other mutually-agreed upon
considerations between the employer and the employee” but this option did not soften the
opposition to the bill. Id. The chief executive of the Greater Boston Chamber of Commerce,
Jim Rooney commented, “It creates a dynamic in which one employer would have to basically
pay someone for not working… this does not feel right.” See Jon Chesto, “Bill to Limit Non-
compete deals includes a surprise catch”. https://www.bostonglobe.com/business/2016/05/16/
bill-limiting-noncompete-agreements-advances-with-contentious-provision/bfGSYp0oCW6U
VSQH4LMaBM/story.html
96 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
compromises needed for the Massachusetts House and Senate to pass
new legislation. The “garden leave” provision was difficult for
employers and some legislators to accept.
61
Proponents are now
waiting to go forward in next year’s legislative session.
The vibrancy of California’s Silicon Valley innovation economy due
in part to information sharing facilitated by worker mobility unfettered
by non-compete agreements is well established.
62
It has been
encumbered somewhat however, by practices where major employers
including Google and Apple allegedly agreed with each other not to hire
away each other’s employees, a factor contradicting the mobility of
employees in high tech firms in Silicon Valley.
63
Metropolitan Boston has enormous core strengths in technology
derived from MIT, Harvard, its other major universities and its world
class research based hospitals. Boston leads the world in start-up
activity in biotech, and there is solid growth in tech industries as well.
64
Moreover, there is a surge in innovation in Intelligence Systems, where
start-ups are building out infrastructure for practical applications of
Intelligence Systems.
65
Appropriate adjustments to its non-compete
legal infrastructure will enhance Boston’s future growth.
IV SUGGESTED GUIDANCE AND CONCLUSIONS
A case can be made to ban employee non-compete agreements like
California, North Dakota and Oklahoma,
66
however all other states
provide some measure of enforcements of non-compete agreements to
protect legitimate business interests of employers.
67
Recent court
decisions previously presented have exposed the misuse of non-
competes and their adverse impact on employees ability to bargain for
better pay and find new better paying jobs. Aware of the abuses and
accepting in part the California experience that banning non-competes
61
See Jon Chesto, “Bill Limiting Non-compete Agreements Advances With
Contentious Provisions” https://www.bostonglobe.com/business/2016/05/16.
62
See supra note 45, p. 22.
63
See U.S. v. Adobe Systems, Inc.; Apple Inc.; Google Inc.; Intel Corp.; Intuit Inc. and
Pixar, 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 83756 at *5 (D. D.C. Mar. 17, 2011) where defendants
agreed that they participated in at least one agreement in violation of the Sherman Act
and each defendant was enjoined from attempting to enter into, any agreement with any
other person to in any way refrain from soliciting, cold calling, recruiting, or otherwise
competing for employees of the other person. See also Steve Musil “Apple/Google offer
$415 million to Settle Anti-pouching Suit – SNET”, Jan. 15, 2015, www.CNET.com.
64
Todd Hickson “The Boston Tech Startup Ecosystem Is Making a Strong Comeback”,
April 8, 2016, www.forbes.com.
65
Id.
66
RUSSELL BECK, EMPLOYMENT NONCOMPETES A STATE BY STATE SURVEY (July 31,
2016).
67
Id.
2017 / Developing Law of Employee Non-Competition Agreements / 97
advances the innovation economy of a region, many states are looking
to update their non-compete laws. Some trends may be found in the
cases previously set forth in this paper.
A. Misuse of Non-compete By Employers
The Jimmy Johns Sandwich Shops non-competes are a clear abuse
of a legal framework meant to protect employers legitimate business
interests, by limiting the mobility of its at-will low wage workers and
locking them into their current employment.
68
While Jimmy Johns
asserts that it does not enforce these agreements, the clear agreement
language calling for the employer to assess all costs and attorney fees
on employees to enforce the agreement, has a chilling and restrictive
effect on employees and is a misuse of the non-compete framework.
69
The Genex Cooperative, Inc. enforcement cases from Washington
state identified the misuse of restrictive covenants by an employer to
eliminate competition and to strong arm at-will, low wage agriculture
employees to accept ever-dwindling wages and restrict their freedom
to work.
70
In the Elizabeth Grady Massachusetts case the court refused to
grant a preliminary injunction because the employer’s true motivation
was to thwart ordinary competition from conventionally skilled service
providers.
71
The trouble and expense of the litigation itself was an
abuse suffered by low wage workers and should be corrected by
legislation.
B. Strict Applications of the Non-compete Agreements Regarding
Functions, Geographic Scope and Duration.
Avoiding competition is not a legitimate business interest, while
protecting business plans and methods and other confidential
information can properly support a non-compete agreement.
Reasonable restrictions on occupational functions (job duties) and
geographic and duration restrictions vary depending on each
individual businesses circumstances and the employees in question.
Unreasonable restrictions will not be well received by a court at the
preliminary injunction stage as seen in the two Virginia cases
previously presented, one involving an overbroad “function” and the
other overbroad in geographic scope.
72
Virginia courts have declined
68
Madigan, supra note 40.
69
Id.
70
Genex, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS at *18.
71
Elizabeth Grady, 2016 Mass. Super LEXIS 34 at *11.
72
NVR Inc. 2017 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 21829 at * 21.
98 / Vol. 50 / Business Law Review
to “blue pencil” overbroad non-compete agreements.
73
In the Genex
case the court stated it had the equitable power to modify an
unreasonable covenant to enforce its basic purpose but refused to do so
based on the facts of record in the case before it.
74
Employers should not risk relying on the courts to blue pencil
overbroad non-compete agreements and should customize non-
competes for the various categories of high level employees in its
workforce as to functions, geography and duration.
75
C. Garden Leave
“Garden leave” should not have been an obstruction to reaching
legislative accord on a non-compete bill as happened in Massachusetts.
Such unusual contractual arrangements are best left to the contracting
parties to work out.
In a “garden leave clause” in an employment contract, the employee
must give a certain amount of notice to the employer in advance of the
employee’s resignation from employment. In exchange, the employer
does not require the employee to come into work during the period of
the leave, and the employee will receive full wages and benefits, and
can spend his or her time “in the garden”.
76
During the leave the
employee cannot work for a competitor. However, on leave the
employee also cannot access confidential records and will be unable to
directly solicit clients or co-workers.
77
Given the costs to the employer
of paying salary and benefits during the period of garden leave, the
employer must carefully identify the type of employee that warrants a
garden leave, such as senior executives, key technical employees and
employees who have access to confidential information. Enforceability
of garden leaves are also in doubt.
78
73
See Lanmark Tech. Inc., v. Canales, 454 F.Supp 2d 524, 529 (E.D. Va. 2006). Better
Living Components, Inc. v. Coleman, 62005 WL 771592 at *5 (Va. Cir. Ct. Apr.6, 2005).
74
Genex, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS at *17.
75
See Wis. Stat. § 103465, where the state of Wisconsin applies an “all or nothing”
reading of noncompete agreements.
76
See Jeffrey S. Klein and Nicholas Pappas, “Garden Leave” Clauses in Lieu of Non-
competes, www.NYLJ.com, vol. 241 No. 24 (Feb 5, 2009).
77
Id.
78
See Bear, Stearns v. Sharon, 550 F.Supp. 2d 174 (D. Mass. 2008) where such a
clause was denied enforcement because the balance of hardship weighed to the
individual employee and his clients.