of Social Work & Social Welfare
Reversing Extreme Inequality
American Academy of Social Work and Social Welfare
aaswsw.org
Reversing Extreme Inequality
Laura Lein
University of Michigan
Jennifer L. Romich
University of Washington
Michael Sherraden
Washington University in St. Louis
Working Paper No. 16
January 2016
Grand Challenge: Reduce Extreme Economic Inequality
Working Paper
The Grand Challenges for Social Work are designed to focus a world of thought and action on the most compelling
and critical social issues of our day. Each grand challenge is a broad but discrete concept where social work
expertise and leadership can be brought to bear on bold new ideas, scientific exploration and surprising innovations.
We invite you to review the following challenges with the goal of providing greater clarity, utility and meaning to
this roadmap for lifting up the lives of individuals, families and communities struggling with the most fundamental
requirements for social justice and human existence.
The Grand Challenges for Social Work include the following:
Ensure healthy development of all youth
Close the health gap
Stop family violence
Eradicate social isolation
End homelessness
Promote smart decarceration
Reduce extreme economic inequality
Build financial capability for all
Harness technology for social good
Create social responses to a changing
environment
Achieve equal opportunity and justice
Advance long and productive lives
Co-Chairs
John Brekke Rowena Fong
University of Southern California University of Texas at Austin
Claudia Coulton
Case Western Reserve University
Diana DiNitto
University of Texas at Austin
Marilyn Flynn
University of Southern California
J. David Hawkins
University of Washington
James Lubben
Boston College
Ronald W. Manderscheid
National Association of County
Behavioral Health & Developmental
Disability Directors
Yolanda C. Padilla
University of Texas at Austin
Michael Sherraden
Washington University in St. Louis
Eddie Uehara
University of Washington
Karina Walters
University of Washington
James Herbert Williams
University of Denver
Richard Barth (ex officio)
American Academy of Social Work and
Social Welfare and University of
Maryland
Sarah Christa Butts (staff)
American Academy of Social Work and
Social Welfare and University of
Maryland
Working Paper
Reversing Extreme Inequality
Laura Lein, Jennifer L. Romich, and Michael Sherraden
Extreme economic inequality has taken hold in the United States. Fostered in part by
misguided policies and intentional choices, it can be reversed through purposeful action.
However, social policies created for the industrial age face relentless political opposition
and are not meeting the social welfare challenges of the information age. A new social
contract is required. This paper elaborates key components of that contract, identifying
social innovations to increase income at the bottom of society and reduce wealth
disparities. Through such innovations, the United States can reverse extreme economic
inequality. Because of social work’s history in addressing injustice and reforming policy,
the profession is uniquely positioned to take on this challenge and has critical roles to
play in addressing it.
Key words: Child care, Earned Income Tax Credit, education, home equity, human
capital, income, inequality, retirement, tax credit, unemployment insurance, wealth.
Modern economies in many countries are generating more wealth than at any other time in history,
yet divisions and disparities are increasing, with concentrated flows of income to the top and
capital accumulation mostly by those who are already wealthy. Extreme inequality in the early
years of the 21st century raises questions of decency and morality, and it leads to negative systemic
outcomes: slower economic growth, increased social dysfunction, and rising political instability.
Today it is clear that the United States is experiencing extreme inequality. For the benefit of
individual households and the society as a whole, it should be reversed (McCall, 2013).
For the most part, the pattern of extreme inequality has emerged from social and economic
policies and practices. It can be reversed by improving strategies for social and economic
development. In other words, we need not be resigned to hand wringing and despair. The United
States has arrived at extreme inequality because of intentional choices as a society, and this trend
can be reversed through purposeful action.
THE INCREASE IN INEQUALITY
There are several reasons for the growth of income inequality in the United States. Foremost,
labor has received an ever smaller share of the total economic product over time as capital has
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 4
Working Paper
captured more. In the United States and in other industrialized economies, business owners have
claimed an increasing amount of total income, and this trend has accelerated since the 1980s
(Elsby, Hobijn, & Şahin, 2013; Karabarbounis & Neiman, 2013).
Within labor’s shrinking share of total output, income is becoming more unequal. Those at the
bottom of the income distribution have seen actual declines in wages since 1979, and half of all
workers have seen little or no growth in hourly wages since 2000 (Gould, 2014). One quarter
(25.3%) of U.S. workers have low pay by the international comparative standard (i.e., less than
two thirds of the median wage). This puts the United States at the very bottom in comparison
with other countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. On
average, 16% of the workers in member countries have low pay (Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development, 2014). At the other end of the earnings distribution, the top 10%
of earners have captured almost all of the growth in labor income over the last two decades, and
growth for the wealthiest has been especially noteworthy, with the top 1% of the income
distribution capturing 55% of total real income growth (Saez, 2015). It is commonplace today for
heads of companies to earn hundreds of times as much as the average income brought home by
their workers. These trends have led to hardship among ordinary workers and concentrated
income poverty.
Over the same 36-year period, nonwage compensation and emerging employment practices have
exacerbated income differences and further undermined earnings potential for the lowest earners.
The highest-paid jobs in our economy are marked by stable wages with the potential for
increases, flexible (if demanding) schedules, and important fringe benefits (e.g., paid time off,
retirement plans, and high-quality health insurance). In contrast to these so-called good jobs, the
positions held by workers at the low end offer little opportunity for advancement and few
valuable benefits. The workers have scant control over their own job demands and schedules
(Kalleberg, 2011). These differences exacerbate income disparities. Paid time off protects
income from the adverse effects of personal or family illness and supports healthy rest;
differential access to paid time off means that many low earners fall further behind when health
needs arise. Scheduling practices have also become a source of instability for low-wage hourly
workers. Employers who once hired workers for a fixed number of hours per week have adopted
on-demand, or dynamic, scheduling practices, whereby workers’ schedules and shift lengths vary
in response to daily or even hourly fluctuations in the employer’s needs. These practices are
increasingly widespread in the hospitality and retail industries, where workersnot their
employersnow bear the costs of fluctuating customer demand (Henly & Lambert, 2010, 2014).
Through such practices, firm earnings are shifted from labor to management and ownership.
For example, consider an employer like Wal-Mart, which increases its own profit margin by
relying on public policiesfood stamps, the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), and other public
programs—to supplement workers’ pay. In effect, taxpayer money is supporting wealth building
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 5
Working Paper
by the owners of Wal-Mart (Jacobs, 2015; Jacobs, Perry, & MacGillvary, 2015). This is a
shameful excess of capitalism. It is harmful to the nation as a whole and should be controlled.
Changes to public assistance and income tax policy amplify labor market inequalities. To date,
public policies in the United States have done little to address extreme income inequality. In fact,
since the middle of the 20th century, our income-tax system has grown less progressive,
amplifying rather than dampening changes in the market. As inequality accelerated in the last
decades of the 20th century, public assistance for those who were impoverished became more
limited and more dependent on labor force participation.
Evidence from outside the United States indicates that public policies can make a real difference,
and many other countries offer more generous social-welfare benefits; U.S. social policies
provide families in poverty with limited cash and in-kind transfers though a patchwork of
special-purpose programs (Garfinkel, Rainwater, & Smeeding, 2010). Broad rules limit program
use and restrict eligibility for programs. In addition, the United States tends to devolve policies
to states and localities instead of administering them at the national level. This sets the stage for
federal funding cuts and differences in the adequacy of benefits across different parts of the
country.
Wealth inequality (commonly measured by net worth) has also increased, reaching levels not
seen since the roaring 1920s and the Gilded Age of the late-19th century. Inequality in wealth
was greatly compounded by the Great Recession (20072009) and its stubborn aftermath. Fiscal
and monetary policies following the recession have also played roles by supporting the financial
sector at the expense of ordinary households. In the United States, the top 1% of wealth holders
own over three times as much as the bottom 80% (Wolff, 2014).
There are particularly extreme differences in wealth across racial and ethnic groups. Today,
depending on the data set used, the median net worth of White households is 10 to 20 times
greater than the median net worth of African American and Hispanic households (Taylor,
Kochhar, Fry, Velasco, & Motel, 2011). If accumulated wealth is the resource that enables
families to make long-term investments in education, homeownership, enterprise, and
development, then this wealth inequality is quite different from income inequalityand
ultimately more harmful (Sherraden, 1991).
How did wealth inequality become so extreme? We usually turn to the market and its cruel
arithmetic for answers to this question, but wealth inequality is also a function of public policy.
The main stores of wealth for most American households are owned homes and savings in
retirement accounts. Both are highly subsidized by public policy via tax benefits. Homeowners
receive a tax deduction for the interest paid on their mortgages, and savings in retirement
accounts are sheltered from tax exposure. The total tax benefits for homes and retirement
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 6
Working Paper
accounts today exceed $200 billion dollars per year, and nearly all of this public subsidy goes to
the top half of the income distributionindeed, most of it goes to the top 10% and especially to
the top 1% (Congressional Budget Office, 2013; Sherraden, 1991).There are no such benefits for
people who do not own their homes or have retirement savings. This public policy is shameful in
every respect. Wealthy households, which do not need the assistance, typically receive tens of
thousands of dollars per year in these sorts of public subsidies, while very few impoverished
households receive any of these subsidies at all.
This same patternsubstantial and stable subsidies for the wealthiest households but meager and
uncertain benefits for the poor and lower middle classappears in different guises in other areas
of social and tax policy. Most would agree that the government should not be in the business of
exacerbating inequality, yet this empirical reality persists with little political opposition or public
outcry.
What has caused these conditions? Capitalism often gets the blame and, in truth, has earned this
reputation. Capitalism is of course a very productive economic system, but it is also prone to
excesses, and excesses must be constrained. Both older research and more recent work in
economics show that the nature of capital is to concentrate; unless intervention prevents it,
owners of capital will accrue a greater and greater share of a society’s production over time (e.g.,
George, 1880; Piketty, 2014). This is not a radical assessment; it is only a clear-eyed and
practical observation.
Evidence is now building in the United States and in other countries that current economic
disparities are dysfunctional for the whole economy and society. Inequality contributed to the
U.S. financial crash of 2007 and the Great Recession, as workers augmented their stagnant
salaries by taking on increasingly unsustainable levels of debt (Van Treeck, 2014). Citizens of
more equal countries live longer, enjoy better health, and report more trust in one another than do
those who live in less equal countries (Wilkinson & Pickett, 2010). When the level of inequality
in a nation broadly affects the health and longevity of its population as well as the foundation of
social relations, everyone has an interest in addressing this dysfunction.
As a result of these conditions, increasing inequality is visible on many fronts. The number of
people in poverty is higher now than it was 20 years ago (U.S. Census Bureau, 2013), and the
impoverished population is different. More families are living in extreme poverty. Remarkably,
nearly 20% of impoverished nonelderly households with children are living on $2 per day or
less, and the prevalence of such households rose dramatically between 1996 and 2011 (Edin &
Shaefer, 2015). These families are often without employment or public assistance and struggle to
meet daily needs. Their lived experiences include days with insufficient food and periods of
unstable housing (Seefeldt & Horowski, 2012). Extreme poverty leaves families debilitated by
debt, and untreated medical conditions are common. Many of the consequences are harmful for
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 7
Working Paper
children. They include negative health effects and disruptions in schooling (Holzer,
Schanzenbach, Duncan, & Ludwig, 2008; Yoshikawa, Aber, & Beardslee, 2012).
The changing nature of jobs leaves the working poor particularly vulnerable to financial
difficulties. In hospitality industries, for example, employees encounter variable hours. If
business is slow, they can be sent home early; if business picks up unexpectedly, they can be
called in at the last minute. The demand for flexibility makes it difficult for workers to cobble
together enough hours of employment (Henly & Lambert, 2010, 2014; Lambert, Fugiel, &
Henly, 2014), and the challenges of parenting with low income are exacerbated by shifts that fall
outside of the regular workday. Both factors make it very difficult to plan for and secure child
care (Henly & Lambert, 2010, 2014; Lambert, 2014; see below). The lack of employer-
sponsored health-insurance benefits leaves workers without medical coverage and vulnerable to
the financial impact of health emergencies (Angel, Lein, & Henrici, 2006). These conditions can
make it virtually impossible for families to save and accumulate resources.
Although unemployment rates are slowly declining, underemployment and unemployment
continue to affect hourly employees, who have fewer work hours than they need. For both men
and women, the likelihood of having a stable, full-time job with benefits continues to decline.
Parents struggle to support their children and households at a level above destitution. In this
context, low-income families rarely have complete health insurance coverage over time (Angel
et al., 2006).
In addition to the challenges of finding child care that can accommodate fluctuating schedules,
many low-income families cannot afford safe, high-quality care for their children. Market-rate
care is very expensive relative to typical incomes. In 10 states, including the large population
centers of California, New York, and Illinois, center-based infant care exceeds 14% of the annual
income of the median married couplesuch care would cost between one third and two thirds of
the income of a single parent (Child Care Aware of America, 2015). For the lowest earners, child
care options and access to child care subsidies are constrained by cost and availability. Although
states draw federal funds to provide subsidized child care for low-income families, subsidies are
limited, and many families find themselves on long wait lists. Availability of child care subsidies
has declined in most states over the past decade. Fewer than one in five children from poor
families receives subsidies, though there is variation across the states (Bruch, Meyers, &
Gornick, 2014). High market costs and limited subsidies mean that many low-income workers
cannot afford child care at all and therefore must rely on strained combinations of kin and self-
care.
Low-income families under such pressures are unlikely to accumulate even modest assets.
Without resources to fall back upon, they have no buffer against sudden declines in income or
sudden increases in expenses. Both are common features of living in poverty. Moreover, the
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 8
Working Paper
difficulty of accruing financial resources prevents investments for parents’ advancement and
their children’s future. It is not surprising that social mobility and economic mobility have
declined. Families in poverty are increasingly unlikely to escape it.
As mobility has become increasingly constrained, families in poverty have lost access to options
for advancement. They have become less able to accrue the financial resources necessary for
investment in their own advancement or in their children’s future. They also have become less
able to amass the assets necessary to buffer the effects of future adversities. They face increased
likelihood of long-term destitution and indebtedness.
RESPONDING TO EXTREME INEQUALITY
We have arrived at a historical transition: The social policies created for the industrial age,
especially policies for the most disadvantaged, now face persistent political opposition and are
not meeting the social welfare challenges of the information age. A new social contract is
required, with particular attention to social policy innovations that support economic stability
and development, especially at the bottom. Below we succinctly present promising and
achievable policies to shore up incomes of the poor, build middle-class stability and wealth, and
reverse the mechanisms that concentrate wealth solely among the wealthy.
Strategies to Increase Incomes at the Bottom
Increase earnings from low-skilled jobs
Low-wage workers and advocates have begun mobilizing to demand better wages and more
predictable pay. Spurred by the protests of fast-food workers, cities and states are taking the lead
in raising the minimum wage to a new standard of $15 per hour (National Employment Law
Project, 2015). Several localities have passed industry-specific or general wage increases that
bring all workers to this standard, and additional efforts are underway. National legislation to
increase the federal minimum wage has been introduced but is currently stalled (H.R. 3164,
2015; S. 1832, 2015). Social workers are already engaged in and should continue advocating for
reforms at local, state, and federal levels. The profession also continues to document effects of
inadequate pay in the lives of impoverished families. Social work’s professional organizations
should propose and support policy reforms. In jurisdictions where wage reforms have been
adopted, social workers can inform clients and support enforcement if the policies are violated.
Social work researchers will continue to collect evidence on wage adequacy and assess efficacy
of policy reforms.
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 9
Working Paper
Make part-time, shift, and variable work more humane
Like higher pay rates, guarantees of sufficient work hoursin the form of reporting-time pay
laws or other such measures—can add stability to workers’ lives and enhance the adequacy of
their total earnings.
1
It is unreasonable and harmful to workers if the structure of part-time work
is completely subject to the whims of employers. Other countries and some U.S. states have set
standards for minimum shift length and on-call time compensation. Federal laws should limit the
demands that employers can put on workers, specifying the allowable extent of flexibility and
instability in hours and income (Lambert, 2014). A positive approach would be to offer
incentives that encourage workplace responsiveness to circumstances in the lives of employees
and their familiesincentives such as preferential consideration in public contracts for firms
with documented family-friendly policies. Social workers should advocate at all levels for
policies that guarantee minimum hours as well as pay for reporting and on-call time. In
jurisdictions that have adopted such policies, social workers can educate clients and the public
about their rights and protections, directing workers to appropriate authorities if omissions occur.
Social work researchers long have played central roles in tracking business-practice trends and
effects of those trends in workers’ lives. This work will continue to inform strategies to improve
working conditions.
Expand the EITC
The EITC has become the major income-support policy for low-income households. By tying the
size of the credit to the number of children in the household, this postmarket transfer targets
more support to low-income households with greater need. The EITC has bipartisan support, and
efforts are underway to expand it. Reforms should include extending the credit to workers who
are parents but do not claim dependent children. Many of them are noncustodial parents. By
extending the credit to them, policymakers will somewhat reduce poverty and inequality. Social
workers should support the EITC, educate clients and the public about it, and work with allied
professionals to enable eligible households to claim it. Social workers will continue to monitor
for-profit tax-preparation firms, which serve as the intermediaries for most claimants. Important
to consider are increases in the protection against predatory financial practices related to
claiming the credit, worker control over when they access the value of the credit, and the number
of alternatives for effective use of the credit, including saving a portion of it.
1
Reporting-time pay provisions “require employers to pay workers for a minimum number of hours for shifts they
report to work” (Lambert, Haley-Lock, & Henly, 2010, p. 11). Eight states, the District of Columbia, and Puerto
Rico have reporting-time laws (Center for Law and Social Policy, Retail Action Project, & Women Employed,
2014).
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 10
Working Paper
Expand child care to enable stable employment
Difficulties in finding and affording child care are important barriers for low-income parents
trying to achieve stable income and develop assets. Child care is a necessarily time-limited
benefit; parents use full-time care only until children enter school and cease using care when
children become self-sufficient. Middle- and high-earning families are eligible for the Child and
Dependent Care Credit, a modest tax credit to partially offset the cost of care. But because the
credit is nonrefundable (the credit may not exceed the amount a filer owes), low-wage workers
with low tax liability cannot claim it.
State and federal policies should expand supports for child care to ensure that they are available
for all working families. Investing in high quality care for low-income children is expensive but
also highly efficient relative to other public investments (Heckman, 2011). Recent state and city
expansions of prekindergarten schooling represent progress toward public provision of safe and
stimulating environments for young children. Social work research and practice have provided
important insights that inform public policy in this area. Social workers will continue
collaborating with allied professionals to promote quality care.
Expand active employment creation
Although publicly supported job-creation strategies have fallen out of favor, they have
historically had considerable impact on national economic stability and the ability of low-income
families to maintain their households. When the private market fails to provide sufficient jobs
paying enough for workers to support their household needs, public jobs can provide
opportunities and labor for projects that create public good. The Works Progress Administration
and Civilian Conservation Corps (CCC), both responses to the Great Depression, together
represent the apex of American public-employment efforts. These programs built many lasting
public amenities. For example, the CCC built many of the state parks in America and planted
more trees than had ever been planted in the nation’s history (Sherraden, 1979). The WPA built
many public buildings and parks. Its cultural workers documented America’s geography,
landscapes, and histories (Sherraden, 1979).
Similar public employment policies might be enacted today. For example, a “CCC for the
twenty-first century,if comparable in size, could employ about one million young people
(Sherraden, 2014, p. 32). But public jobs programs are politically controversial today; private
industry tends to view them as unfair competition or inconsistent with capitalist goals (Rose,
1989). Since the mid-20th century, public policies for job creation have most often taken the
form of incentives for private industry. For instance, the American Recovery and Reinvestment
Act of 2009 offered job-creation incentives, and the “vast majority” of jobs credited to it were in
private firms that received government-funded grants or contracts (Council of Economic
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 11
Working Paper
Advisors, 2009, p. 6). Creating better evidence on the effectiveness and distributional impacts of
job creation policies should be a priority. As social workers Frances Perkins and Harry Hopkins
did for President Franklin Roosevelt in the 1930s (Downey, 2009; Hopkins, 2008), social
workers today can lead in developing, implementing, and evaluating innovations in employment
creation.
Strengthen unemployment insurance
Unemployment insurance provides an important buffer to protect workers who find themselves
out of a job. However, many low-wage workers do not qualify because they do not meet the
program’s minimum-earnings or job-tenure requirements. The standards were designed for
workers with so-called good jobs, not those in contingent or schedule-restricted positions
(Shaefer, 2010). Changes to the requirements would extend this key support to the families least
able to weather a spell of joblessness (Levine, 2006). Indeed, states have reacted to the 2009
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act by enacting reforms to strengthen the program;
families have fared better in states that implemented the unemployment insurance reforms than
in states that did not (Chang, 2015). In some cases, unemployment insurance is not an option.
Temporary Assistance for Needy Families remains a significant bridging program for those
families in difficulty. In this difficult job market, families may require support when adults are
between jobs, injured, or ill. Since the profession’s inception, social workers have helped
families to access these programs, delivered supports, and tested sustainable improvements to the
safety net. At national and state levels, social workers can continue to advocate for inclusive
unemployment insurance and effective temporary relief for those who do not qualify.
Stop privileging income from capital over income from labor in the tax system
One income-oriented strategy that targets the wealthy should be put squarely on the table. In
future budget-reform negotiations, favorable treatment of capital earnings should be eliminated
because it is unfair and counterproductive policy. It does little for the economy and increases
inequality. This tax change would (a) reduce incomes at the top, where so much of the total
income comes from capital; (b) raise public revenue, creating resources that could support
incomes at the bottom; (c) remove the distortion between investment in capital and investment in
labor, leading to greater investment in labor, increases in employment opportunities, and wage
growth. The change touches upon the trifecta of inequality and would have huge positive effects.
The profession is perhaps uniquely positioned to make this case. Social work researchers have
produced a body evidence on the effects of capital-oriented strategies in the lives of families, and
insights from practice complement this evidence, suggesting effective ways to frame the relevant
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 12
Working Paper
issues. Moreover, social work’s commitments to social and economic justice give the profession
leverage and credibility in public discussions about fairness of policy choices.
Strategies to Reduce Wealth Inequality
Several policy changes offer promising ways to reduce wealth inequality. We identify several
elephants in the room. Progressive advocates should shine a light on them.
Redeploy wealth-building subsidies in retirement
Federal and state governments spend well over $100 billion per year in tax benefits to support
retirement accounts, mostly for the already well-off (Congressional Budget Office, 2015; Joint
Committee on Taxation, 2015). This support, at minimum, should be equally distributed across
the population (a fair policy). Ideally, more of the support would go to lower income households
(a progressive policy).
Social workers should lead discussions about distributing public subsidies more fairly, and even
progressively. In these discussions, they should identify priorities and specific policy designs that
protect those who need support in their older years. At the same time, social workers will
continue to inform and engage in debates about Social Security retirement and its protections for
those with lowest incomes.
Redeploy wealth-building subsidies for shelter
As with retirement subsidies, the more than $100 billion in annual public subsidies for homes,
mostly in the form of the home-mortgage interest tax deduction (Congressional Budget Office,
2015), should be redeployed so that the distribution is at least fair and ideally progressive. If
there is to be a public subsidy for shelter, then at minimum each household should have the same
amount, regardless of whether they are owning or renting.
More generally, the United States is in need of an institutional strategy for universal, lifelong,
and progressive asset building. Such a strategy may have several components.
Create a new lifelong policy of inclusive and progressive wealth building
Such a policy can begin with accounts for all children at birth and evolve into a lifelong system
that builds wealth for education, homes, other life goals (Sherraden, 1991). This policy system
could eventually become a supplement for retirement security. The policy goal is not far-fetched;
it can happen. During 2014, three states (Maine, Nevada, and Rhode Island) announced the
implementation of universal and automatic accounts for children. Policy innovations in the states
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 13
Working Paper
are ongoing, and there is a positive, bipartisan, federal discussion (Beverly, Clancy, Huang, &
Sherraden, 2015)
Social workers are already leading efforts to build and test the features of universal and
progressive asset-building policies. As that work continues, the profession should advocate for
the broadest adoption of effective measures. In related work, the profession should also
reincorporate financial capability practice into the professional training curriculum (Sherraden et
al., 2015). This training was an integral part of social work practice in the first half of the 20th
century, and it is now time to reestablish it.
Reduce the role of income and wealth in building human capital
In addition to strengthening opportunities for private saving, we should continue to scrutinize
education funding models that do not benefit the full population effectively. In primary and
secondary education, this includes local tax-based funding for public schooling. Such a funding
model is inherently unfair.
This also includes the shift away from public investment in postsecondary education. Earning a
college degree is the surest step toward a middle class life, yet American higher educationonce
an engine of our middle-class democracyis slowly morphing into a replicator of economic
inequities. The children of the wealthy are more likely to enter and finish college than are the
children of low- and middle-income parents (Bailey & Dynarski, 2011). Moreover, poor and
middle-class students who gain entry but cannot pay outright must borrow, mortgaging their
future earnings to pay for college.
In short, a major funding shift has occurred: Basic postsecondary education, once a public
responsibility shared by taxpayers and families, has become a private responsibility met
primarily by students and their parents, with long-term implications for the financial positions of
all parties. College graduates from low- and moderate-income families now spend nontrivial
parts of their first two decades of work repaying student loans instead of accumulating resources
for their future (Elliott, 2015).
At every level, social workers can design, study, and advance policy innovations that increase
access to quality education and promote successful educational completion. This should happen
for reasons of decency and fairness, and also because this is the best possible investment strategy
for the future of the nation as a whole.
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 14
Working Paper
Getting There from Here
In sum, inequality in the United States today creates hardship for households, a suboptimal
economy, and social instability. One important insight is that inequality is not caused solely by
the market. Misguided public policies have fostered inequality; thus, a partial remedy lies in the
design and implementation of more positive policies. The United States can reverse extreme
economic inequality.
Achieving the goals discussed here will require advances in policy design and changes in public
will. The grandness of this challenge lies not in the depth of the required technical knowledge
but in the daunting task of crafting and executing political changes within legislative systems that
are too often beholden to the interests of the wealthy. Demanding work remains, but social
workers have a long and honorable history of pointing out the injustices, recommending better
policies, and working very hard for those social innovations.
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 15
Working Paper
REFERENCES
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-5, 123 Stat. 115 (2011).
Angel, R. J., Lein, L., & Henrici, J. (2006). Poor families in America’s health care crisis: How
the other half pays. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Bailey, M. J., & Dynarski, M. (2011). Inequality in postsecondary education. In G. J. Duncan &
R. J. Murnane (Eds.), Whither opportunity? Rising inequality, schools, and children’s life
chances (pp. 117131). New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.
Beverly, S., Clancy, M., Huang, J., & Sherraden, M. (2015). The SEED for Oklahoma Kids Child
Development Account experiment: Accounts, assets, earnings, and savings (CSD Research
Brief No. 15-29). Retrieved from Washington University, center for Social Development
website: http://csd.wustl.edu/Publications/Documents/RB15-29.pdf
Bruch, S. K., Meyers, M. K., & Gornick, J. C. (2015). Separate and unequal: Decentralization,
state policy choice, and inequalities in safety net assistance. Unpublished manuscript.
University of Iowa, Iowa City.
Center for Law and Social Policy, Retail Action Project, & Women Employed. (2014). Tackling
unstable and unpredictable work schedules: A policy brief on guaranteed minimum hours
and reporting pay policies [Policy brief]. Retrieved from http://www.clasp.org/resources-and
-publications/publication-1/Tackling-Unstable-and-Unpredictable-Work-Schedules-3-7-2014
-FINAL-1.pdf
Chang, Y.-L. (2015). State unemployment insurance modernization and economic recovery of
American working-age families after the Great Recession. Unpublished manuscript, School
of Social Work, University of Washington, Seattle.
Child Care Aware of America. (2015). Parents and the high cost of child care: 2015 report.
Retrieved from http://usa.childcareaware.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/12/Parents-and-the
-High-Cost-of-Child-Care-2015-FINAL.pdf
Congressional Budget Office. (2013). The budget and economic outlook: Fiscal years 2013 to
2023 (Report No. 4649). Retrieved from https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/113th
-congress-2013-2014/reports/43907-BudgetOutlook.pdf
Congressional Budget Office. (2015). The budget and economic outlook: 2015 to 2025 [Report].
Retrieved from https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/114th-congress-2015-2016/reports
/49892-Outlook2015.pdf
Council of Economic Advisors. (2009). Estimates of job creation from the American Recovery
and Reinvestment Act of 2009. Retrieved from White House website: https://www
.whitehouse.gov/administration/eop/cea/Estimate-of-Job-Creation/
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 16
Working Paper
Downey, K. (2009). The woman behind the New Deal: The life and legacy of Frances Perkins
Social Security, unemployment insurance, and the minimum wage. New York, NY:
Doubleday.
Edin, K. J., & Shaefer, H. L. (2015). $2.00 a day: Living on almost nothing in America. Boston,
MA: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.
Elliott, W. E., III (with Lewis, M. K.). (2015). The real college debt crisis: How student
borrowing threatens financial well-being and erodes the American Dream. Santa Barbara,
CA: Praeger.
Elsby, M. W. L., Hobijn, B., & Şahin, A. (2013). The decline of the U.S. labor share. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, 163. doi:10.1353/eca.2013.0016
Garfinkel, I., Rainwater, L., & Smeeding, T. (2010). Wealth and welfare states: Is America a
laggard or a leader? New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
George, H. (1880). Progress and poverty: An inquiry into the cause of industrial depression, and
of increase of want with increase of wealth; The remedy. New York, NY: Appleton.
Gould, E. (2014). Why America’s workers need faster wage growthand what we can do about
it (Raising America’s Pay Briefing Paper No. 382). Retrieved from Economic Policy Institute
website: http://www.epi.org/publication/why-americas-workers-need-faster-wage-growth/
Heckman, J. J. (2011). The case for investing in disadvantaged young children. Retrieved from
http://heckmanequation.org/content/resource/case-investing-disadvantaged-young-children
Henly, J. R., & Lambert, S. J. (2010). Schedule flexibility and unpredictability in retail:
Implications for employee worklife outcomes (Work Scheduling Study Paper). Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago, School of Social Service Administration.
Henly, J. R., & Lambert, S. J. (2014). Unpredictable work timing in retail jobs: Implications for
employee worklife conflict. ILR Review, 67(3), 9861016. doi:10.1177/0019793914537458
Holzer, H. J., Schanzenbach, D. W., Duncan, G. J., & Ludwig, J. (2008). The economic costs of
childhood poverty in the United States. Journal of Children and Poverty, 14(1), 4161. doi:
10.1080/10796120701871280
Hopkins, J. (2008). Harry Hopkins: Sudden hero, brash reformer. New York, NY: Palgrave
Macmillan.
H.R. 3164, 114th Cong. (2015).
Jacobs, K. (2015, April 15). Americans are spending $153 billion a year to subsidize
McDonald’s and Wal-Mart’s low wage workers. Washington Post. Retrieved from http://
wpo.st/6yA21
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 17
Working Paper
Jacobs, K., Perry, I., & MacGillvary, J. (2015, April). The high public cost of low wages:
Poverty-level wages cost U.S. taxpayers $152.8 billion each year in public support for
working families (Research Brief). Retrieved from University of California, Berkeley, Center
for Labor Research and Education website: http://laborcenter.berkeley.edu/pdf/2015/the-high
-public-cost-of-low-wages.pdf
Joint Committee on Taxation. (2015). Estimates of federal tax expenditures for fiscal years
20152019 (Report No. JCX-141R-15). Retrieved from https://www.jct.gov/publications
.html?func=startdown&id=4857
Kalleberg, A. L. (2011). Good jobs, bad jobs: The rise of polarized and precarious employment
systems in the United States, 1970s to 2000s. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.
Karabarbounis, L., & Neiman, B. (2013). The global decline of the labor share (NBER Working
paper No. 19136). Retrieved from National Bureau of Economic Research website: http://
www.nber.org/papers/w19136
Lambert, S. J. (2014). The limits of voluntary employer action for improving low-level jobs. In
M. G. Crain & M. Sherraden (Eds.), Working and living in the shadow of economic fragility
(pp. 120139). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Lambert, S. J., Fugiel, P. J., & Henly, J. R. (2014). Precarious work schedules among early-
career employees in the US: A national snapshot (Employment Instability, Family Well-
Being, and Social Policy Network Research Brief). Retrieved from University of Chicago
School of Social Service Administration website: https://ssascholars.uchicago.edu/sites
/default/files/work-scheduling-study/files/lambert.fugiel.henly_.precarious_work_schedules
.august2014_0.pdf
Lambert, S. J., Haley-Lock, A., & Henly, J. R. (2010). Work schedule flexibility in hourly jobs:
Unanticipated consequences and promising directions (Work Scheduling Study Working
Paper). Retrieved from University of Chicago, School of Social Service Administration
website: https://ssascholars.uchicago.edu/sites/default/files/work-scheduling-study/files
/lambert_haley-lock_henly_unanticipated_consequences_of_flexibility_in_hourly_jobs
_0.pdf
Levine, P. B. (2006). Unemployment insurance over the business cycle: Does it meet the needs
of less-skilled workers? In R. M. Blank, S. Danziger, & R. F. Schoeni (Eds.), Working and
poor: How economic and policy changes are affecting low-wage workers (pp. 366395).
New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.
McCall, L. (2013). The undeserving rich: American beliefs about inequality, opportunity, and
redistribution. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.
National Employment Law Project. (2015, December 21). 14 cities & states approved $15
minimum wage in 2015 [News release]. Retrieved from http://www.nelp.org/content/uploads
/PR-Minimum-Wage-Year-End-15.pdf
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 18
Working Paper
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. (2014). OECD employment outlook
2014. doi:10.1787/empl_outlook-2014-en
Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century (A. Goldhammer, Trans.). Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Rose, N. E. (1989). Work relief in the 1930s and the origins of the Social Security Act. Social
Service Review, 63(1), 6391. doi:10.1086/603679
S. 1832, 114th Cong. (2015).
Saez, E. (2015). Striking it richer: The evolution of top incomes in the United States [Working
paper]. Retrieved from University of California, Berkley, website: http://eml.berkeley.edu
/~saez/saez-UStopincomes-2014.pdf
Seefeldt, K., & Horowski, M. (2012). The continuum of connection: Low-income families and
economic support during the Great Recession (National Poverty Center Working Paper No.
12-11). Retrieved from University of Michigan, National Poverty Center website: http://npc
.umich.edu/publications/u/2012-11-npc-working-paper.pdf
Shaefer, H. L. (2010). Identifying key barriers to unemployment insurance for disadvantaged
workers in the United States. Journal of Social Policy, 39(3), 439460. doi:10.1017
/S0047279410000218
Sherraden, M. (1979). The Civilian Conservation Corps: Effectiveness of the camps Dissertation
Abstracts International: Section A. Social Sciences, 40(10), 5619.
Sherraden, M. (1991). Assets and the poor: A new American welfare policy. Armonk, NY: M. E.
Sharpe.
Sherraden, M. (2014). Response by Michael Sherraden. In M. G. Crain & M. Sherraden (Eds.),
Working and living in the shadow of economic fragility (pp. 3035). New York, NY: Oxford
University Press.
Sherraden, M. S., Huang, J., Frey, J. J., Birkenmaier, J., Callahan, C., Clancy, M. M., &
Sherraden, M. (2015). Financial capability and asset building for all (Grand Challenges for
Social Work Initiative Working Paper No. 13). Retrieved from American Academy of Social
Work and Social Welfare website: http://aaswsw.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/10/Financial
-Capability-and-Asset-Building-for-All.pdf
Taylor, P., Kochhar, R., Fry, R., Velasco, G., & Motel, S. (2011). Twenty-to-one: Wealth gaps
rise to record highs between Whites, Blacks and Hispanics [Report]. Retrieved from Pew
Research Center, Social and Demographic Trends website: http://www.pewsocialtrends.org
/files/2011/07/SDT-Wealth-Report_7-26-11_FINAL.pdf
U.S. Census Bureau. (2013). Retrieved from http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/poverty/data
/incpovhlth/2013/tables.html
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 19
Working Paper
Van Treeck, T. (2014). Did inequality cause the U.S. financial crisis? Journal of Economic
Surveys, 28(3), 421448. doi:10.1111/joes.12028
Wilkinson, R., & Pickett, K. (2010). The spirit level: Why greater equality makes societies
stronger. New York, NY: Bloomsbury.
Wolff, E. N. (2014). Household wealth trends in the United States, 1962-2013: What happened
over the Great Recession? (NBER Working Paper No. 20733). Retrieved from the National
Bureau of Economic Research website: http://www.nber.org/papers/w20733
Yoshikawa, H., Aber, J. L., & Beardslee, W. R. (2012). The effects of poverty on the mental,
emotional, and behavioral health of children and youth: Implications for prevention.
American Psychologist, 67(4), 272284. doi:10.1037/a0028015
REVERSING EXTREME INEQUALITY 20
Working Paper
ABOUT THE AUTHORS
LAURA LEIN,
2
PhD, is the Katherine Reebel Collegiate Professor of Social Work and Dean in the School
of Social Work, and Professor of anthropology at the University of Michigan.
JENNIFER L. ROMICH, PhD, is Associate Professor in the School of Social Work and Director of the West
Coast Poverty Center at the University of Washington.
MICHAEL SHERRADEN, PhD, is George Warren Brown Distinguished University Professor and founding
Director of the Center for Social Development in the Brown School of Social Work at Washington
University in St. Louis.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Sandra Audia Little at the University of Maryland School of Social Work designed the cover. Chris
Leiker at Washington University’s Center for Social Development provided editorial support and
comments on the manuscript. Marcia Meyers gave input on earlier drafts.
SUGGESTED CITATION
Lein, L., Romich, J. L., & Sherraden, M. (2015). Reversing extreme inequality (Grand Challenges for
Social Work Initiative Working Paper No. 16). Cleveland, OH: American Academy of Social Work and
Social Welfare.
CONTACT
American Academy of Social Work and Social Welfare
Sarah Christa Butts, Assistant to the President
academy@aaswsw.org
2
Corresponding author. Email: leinl@umich.edu.